« Economies of scale as a determinant of trade: beyond comparative advantage » : différence entre les versions

De Baripedia
Aucun résumé des modifications
 
(7 versions intermédiaires par le même utilisateur non affichées)
Ligne 45 : Ligne 45 :
{{Translations
{{Translations
| en = Economies of scale as a determinant of trade: beyond comparative advantage
| en = Economies of scale as a determinant of trade: beyond comparative advantage
| es =  
| es = Las economías de escala como determinantes del comercio: más allá de la ventaja comparativa
}}
}}


Ligne 126 : Ligne 126 :
[[File:économie internationale rappel monopole et concurrence monopolistique 1.png|thumb|center]]
[[File:économie internationale rappel monopole et concurrence monopolistique 1.png|thumb|center]]


== Ouverture au commerce ==
== Open for business ==


Fusion de 2 marchés identiques de <math>n'</math> firmes
Merger of 2 identical markets of <math>n'</math> firms


[[File:économie internationale rappel ouverture au commerce 1.png|thumb|center]]
[[File:économie internationale rappel ouverture au commerce 1.png|thumb|center]]


== Gain du commerce en concurrence monopolistique ==
== Gaining trade in monopolistic competition ==
passage de <math>E^{'}</math> (Autarcie) à <math>E^{''}</math> (libre-échange)
going from <math>E^{'}</math> (Autarky) to <math>E^{'}</math> (Free Trade)
 
Pro-competitive gain
*markup decreases from math>\mu'</math> to math>\mu''</math> and therefore the price decreases from math>p'</math> to math>p''</math>.
*Well-being gains for +C consumers


Gain pro-compétitif
Gain in economies of scale (or rationalization or selection)
*markup diminue de <math>\mu'</math> à <math>\mu''</math> et donc le prix baisse de <math>p'</math> à <math>p''</math>  
*Fewer firms operating on the total market (from <math>2n'</math> to <math>n''</math>) more production per firm (from <math>x'</math> to <math>x''</math>)
*Gain de bien-être pour les consommateurs de +C
*lower average cost


Gain d’économie d’échelle (ou de rationalisation ou sélection)
Gain of varieties
*Moins de firmes en activité sur la totalité du marché (de <math>2n'</math> à <math>n''</math>) plus de production par firme (de <math>x'</math> à <math>x''</math>)
*Increase the number of varieties available to the consumer from <math>n'</math> to <math>n'</math>.
*baisse du coût moyen
*Equal gain for producers (more input varieties available => increases their productivity)


Gain de variétés
Translated with www.DeepL.com/Translator (free version)
*Augmentation du nombre de variétés disponibles pour le consommateur de <math>n'</math> à <math>n''</math>
*Également gain pour les producteurs (plus grand nombre de variétés d’inputs disponibles => augmente leur productivité)


== Remarque ==
== Remark ==


Des firmes disparaissent lors de l'ouverture aux échanges. Dans ce modèle, comme toutes les firmes sont identiques, seul le hasard détermine quelles sont les gagnantes.
Firms disappear when trade is opened up. In this model, as all firms are identical, only chance determines which firms win.


Modèle avec des firmes hétérogènes: toutes les entreprises n'ont pas la même productivité
Model with heterogeneous firms: not all firms have the same productivity


Encore une fois le LE fait des gagnants et des perdants: les grandes entreprises très productives y gagnent, les plus petites voir leur part de marché se réduire et disparaissent.
Once again, LE has winners and losers: large, highly productive companies win, smaller companies see their market share shrink and disappear.


Ce type de modèle permet également d'expliquer que moins de 20% des entreprises manufacturières françaises et américaines exportent, un % encore plus faible investissent à l'étranger.
This type of model also explains why less than 20% of French and American manufacturing companies export, and an even smaller percentage invest abroad.


== Evidence empirique ? ==
== Empirical evidence? ==


Une grande partie du commerce des pays de l’OCDE est intra-industrielle (40% pour l’UE par exemple). Le modèle de commerce avec économies d’échelle permet d’expliquer ceci.
A large part of the trade of OECD countries is intra-industrial (e.g. 40% for the EU). The trade model with economies of scale helps to explain this.


[[File:économie internationale économie échelle interne évidences 1.png|thumb|center|Evolution du poids du commerce intra-branche dans le commerce mondial. (Source: Marius Brülhart, 2009).]]
[[File:économie internationale économie échelle interne évidences 1.png|thumb|center|Evolution of the weight of intra-industry trade in world trade. (Source: Marius Brülhart, 2009).]]


Effet de l'intégration au sein de NAFTA entre les US, Canada et Mexique, cf. section 3 chapitre 6 dans FT (2012)...
Effect of integration within NAFTA between the US, Canada and Mexico, cf. section 3 chapter 6 in FT (2012) .


== Effet de l’intégration commerciale au sein de l’UE-15 ==
== Effect of trade integration within the EU-15 ==
*
*Elimination of tariff barriers (UD in 1968) and especially non-tariff barriers (single market - 1992), then single currency....  
Élimination des barrières tarifaires (UD en 1968) et surtout non-tarifaires (marché unique – 1992) , puis monnaie unique...  
*defragmentation of the European market from 1992 onwards
*défragmentation du marché européen à partir de 1992  
*Increased competition
*Augmentation de la concurrence


On retrouve les effets attendus...
We're getting the effects we expected...


Effet de l’intégration commerciale au sein de l’UE-15 (suite)  
Effect of trade integration within the EU-15 (continued)  


Augmentation de la concurrence
Increased competition


*Gain de variété
*Gain in variety
Mohler et Seitz (2010): gains substantiels entre 1999-2008 pour les petit pays (ex: +0.75% du PIB pour le Danemark, +2.8% pour l'Estonie), faibles pour les grands pays.
Mohler and Seitz (2010): substantial gains between 1999-2008 for small countries (e.g. +0.75% of GDP for Denmark, +2.8% for Estonia), small for large countries.


*Gain pro-compétitif
*Pro-competitive gain
Allen et al. (1999): la mise en place du marché unique a réduit les marges prix-coût d’environ 4% en moyenne.
Allen et al (1999): The implementation of the Single Market reduced price-cost margins by about 4% on average.


*Gain d’économie d’échelle ou de rationalisation
* Gain in economies of scale or rationalisation
*Augmentation de la concurrence
*Increased competition
**Pression sur les profits  
**Pressure on profits  
**Restructuration économique
**Economic restructuring
= moins de firmes, chacune de taille plus importante et en théorie plus efficiente
= fewer firms, each of larger size and theoretically more efficient
**Politique européenne de surveillance de la concurrence
**European Competition Surveillance Policy
**Evolution du nombre de banques dans la Zone Euro
**Change in the number of banks in the Euro Zone
**Essentiellement due à des opérations de fusions-acquisitions dans la zone euro dont 77% ont eu lieu a l’intérieur d’un même pays (surtout pour les plus grands pays)
**Mainly due to M&A activity in the euro zone, 77% of which took place within the same country (especially for the largest countries).


[[File:économie internationale membres de la zone euro illustration 1.png|thumb|center|Membres de la Zone Euro hors Chypre, Estonie, Malte, Slovaquie et Slovénie (Sources: Baldwin and Wyplosz 2012).]]
[[File:économie internationale membres de la zone euro illustration 1.png|thumb|center|Euro area members excluding Cyprus, Estonia, Malta, Slovakia and Slovenia (Sources: Baldwin and Wyplosz 2012).]]


= Les économies d’échelle externes (ou accidents historiques versus avantage comparatif) =
= External economies of scale (or historical accidents versus comparative advantage) =


== Économies d’échelle externes ==
== External economies of scale ==
Selon Marshall, 3 raisons principales pour expliquer les concentrations d’entreprises (i.e. 3 types d’externalités):
According to Marshall, there are 3 main reasons for corporate concentrations (i.e. 3 types of externalities):
#proximité avec un grand nombre de fournisseurs spécialisés / biens intermédiaires non-échangeables;
#Proximity to a large number of specialized suppliers / non-tradable intermediate goods;
#Bassin de main d’œuvre important;
#Large pool of labor;
#Externalités de connaissances.
#Knowledge externalities.


Rendements d’échelle croissants au niveau sectoriel
Increasing returns to scale at sector level


Chaque secteur aura une courbe d’offre décroissante: plus sa production est importante, plus le prix auquel il est prêt à vendre est faible.
Each sector will have a decreasing supply curve: the greater its production, the lower the price at which it is prepared to sell.


[[File:économie internationale économies d’échelle externes illustration 1.png|thumb|center]]
[[File:économie internationale économies d’échelle externes illustration 1.png|thumb|center]]


Accidents historiques peuvent avoir des conséquences importantes sur l’avantage comparatif des pays en présence d’économies d’échelle externes,
Historical accidents can have important consequences on the comparative advantage of countries in the presence of external economies of scale,


La présence d’économies d’échelle externes peut justifier des interventions ponctuelles dans le temps
The presence of external economies of scale may justify ad hoc interventions over time.


[[File:économie internationale économies d’échelle externes illustration 2.png|thumb|center]]
[[File:économie internationale économies d’échelle externes illustration 2.png|thumb|center]]


Plus important encore. Une fois qu’elle produit à <math>P_2</math> l’économie Thaïlandaise peut maintenant satisfaire l’économie mondiale à un Prix <math>P_3</math>.
More importantly. Once it produces at <math>P_2</math> the Thai economy can now satisfy the world economy at a <math>P_3</math> price.


Les restrictions au commerce deviennent un moyen de promouvoir les exportations dans ces modèles. Avec des gains au commerce au niveau mondial (avec les producteurs Suisses qui subissent des pertes).
Trade restrictions become a means of promoting exports in these models. With gains to trade at the world level (with Swiss producers suffering losses).


Cette justification de la protection temporaire d'une industrie est connue sous le nom d'argument de l'industrie naissante.
This justification for temporary protection of an industry is known as the infant industry argument.
*important dans le débat sur le rôle de la politique commerciale dans le processus de développement, notamment en cas de défaillances de marché (imperfection système financier, problème d'appropriation – cf. chapitre 8).
*important in the debate on the role of trade policy in the development process, especially in the case of market failures (imperfection in the financial system, ownership problems - see Chapter 8).
*Difficile d'identifier des cas concrets de succès d'industrialisation par substitution aux importations même si cette stratégie était très répandue dans les PvD dans les 1970s
*It is difficult to identify concrete cases of successful industrialisation through import substitution, even though this strategy was widespread in the developing countries in the 1970s.
*La protection commerciale ne suffit pas pour développer un avantage comparatif et une industrie compétitive (nécessité d'accumuler du capital physique, humain, etc.) + difficile de déterminer quels secteurs nécessitent vraiment un soutien.
*"Trade protection is not enough to develop a comparative advantage and a competitive industry (need to accumulate physical, human capital, etc.)" It is difficult to determine which sectors really need support.


== Extension : L' Économie géographique ==
== Extension: The Geographic Economy ==
{{Article détaillé|Géographie économique}}
{{Article détaillé|Economic geography}}
{{Article détaillé|Échanges et avantages géographiques}}
{{Article détaillé|Trade and geographical advantages}}


Krugman (Nobel 2008) explique les processus d’agglomération spatiale de l’économie et les échanges économiques qui en résultent.
Krugman (Nobel 2008) explains the processes of spatial agglomeration of the economy and the resulting economic exchanges.


=== Les dynamiques d’agglomération ===
=== Agglomeration dynamics ===
Si les entreprises bénéficient de rendements d’échelles internes et qu’il existe des coûts de transport :
If firms benefit from internal returns to scale and there are transport costs :
*Intérêt à se situer à proximité d’un grand marché
*Interest in being close to a large market...
*Implantation de plusieurs entreprises dans une même région
*Setting up several companies in the same region
*Engendre des économies d’échelle externes + augmente la taille du marché (nouveaux producteurs attirent nouveaux travailleurs et donc nouveaux consommateurs)
*Creating external economies of scale" increases the size of the market (new producers attract new workers and therefore new consumers).
*Attire de nouveaux producteurs ... Processus cumulatif d’agglomération spatiale
*Attracting new producers ... Cumulative process of spatial agglomeration


Processus cumulatif d’agglomération spatiale né de la conjonction des économies d’échelle internes et externes
Cumulative process of spatial agglomeration resulting from the conjunction of internal and external economies of scale
*Régions de grande taille se spécialisent dans les secteurs des biens industriels à rendements croissants
*Large regions specializing in industrial goods sectors with increasing returns
*Régions périphériques se spécialisent dans les productions à rendements constants
*Peripheral regions specialize in constant-yield production
*Nouveaux flux d’échanges commerciaux
*New trade flows


Dans les faits toutes les activités à rendements croissants ne se concentrent pas systématiquement dans un lieu unique car il existe des forces de dispersion (contraintes sur mobilité des travailleurs, effet de congestion sur les facteurs immobiles, intensité de la concurrence)
In fact, not all activities with increasing returns are systematically concentrated in a single location because there are forces of dispersion (constraints on worker mobility, congestion effect on immobile factors, intensity of competition).


Krugman (1991): en partant d’une situation où les secteurs industriels avec rendements d’échelle croissants sont équitablement repartis entre les région/pays, la baisse des barrières aux échanges internationaux renforce la probabilité d’avoir un processus cumulatif d’agglomération.
Krugman (1991): Starting from a situation where industrial sectors with increasing returns to scale are evenly distributed across regions/countries, the lowering of barriers to international trade increases the likelihood of a cumulative process of agglomeration.


=== Exemple : Intégration européenne ===
=== Example: European integration ===
[[File:économie internationale exemple intégration européenne 1.png|thumb|right]]
[[File:économie internationale exemple intégration européenne 1.png|thumb|right]]


Pays/régions au centre de l’Europe attirent et se spécialisent (1/7 de la surface mais 1⁄2 de l’activité) + pays/ régions périphériques moins de chance de développer des pôles industriels dynamiques.
Countries/regions in the centre of Europe attract and specialise (1/7 of the surface area but 1⁄2 of the activity) + peripheral countries/regions less likely to develop dynamic industrial clusters.


Creusement des inégalités entre les régions européennes.
Growing inequalities between European regions.


Politique régionale ambitieuse Nécessaire pour contrebalancer les mécanismes de l’agglomération.
Ambitious regional policy Necessary to counterbalance the mechanisms of agglomeration.


Arbitrage entre efficacité Économique et équité spatiale.
Trade-off between economic efficiency and spatial equity.


= Résumé =
= Résumé =

Version actuelle datée du 6 avril 2020 à 18:43


The idea is that the internal market of small countries is not sufficient to allow them to develop economies of scale. Trade with the rest of the world gives access to a larger market.

  • Creating the European single market
  • Canada's entry into NAFTA

But if we have, for example, increasing internal returns to scale:

  • Large firms have an advantage over smaller firms and tend to dominate the market = > imperfect competition = >
  • Products must be differentiated, otherwise in the long run there would simply be one firm in the market => product variety, and intra-industry trade (rather than inter-industry trade as in the Ricardo or HO models).

When economies of scale are present, the production of a good increases more than proportionally to the quantity of factors employed in that sector.

Internal economies of scale: where the unit cost of production depends on the size of each firm but not necessarily on the size of the sector. (e.g. fixed cost of a machine).

External economies of scale: where the unit cost of production (i.e. the average cost) depends on the size of the industry but not necessarily on the size of the individual firm. (e.g. labour pool, non-exchangeable service, etc.).

There are different implications for market structures.

Languages

Modèle de commerce avec économies d’échelle internes[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

Assumptions[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

One product, but a large number of varieties

Économie internationale modèle de commerce avec économies d’échelle internes 1.png

Firms face internal economies of scale, but competition is monopolistic: firms continue to enter the market until profits are zero.

Économie internationale modèle de commerce avec économies d’échelle internes 2.png

Heterogeneous consumers and each consumer has a preferred variety.

Économie internationale modèle de commerce avec économies d’échelle internes 3.png

Two identical countries, but with a different history (therefore different varieties).

Gains from trade (beyond comparative advantage)[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

  1. Pro-competitive gains
  2. Economies of scale gains (or rationalization or selection)
  3. Gains in product variety

Theoretical reminders: Monopoly and monopolistic competition[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

Internal economies of scale are assumed

Representation:

Fixed costs <and constant marginal cost and constant marginal cost.

  • Total cost:
  • Average cost:
  • Marginal cost:

If then => negative profit

Internal economy of scale incompatible with pure competition

Theoretical reminders: Monopoly and monopolistic competition[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

Monopoly[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

One possibility = monopoly

Profit maximization rule: Rmx=Cmx price=pm; quantity=xm, positive profit

Économie internationale rappel monopole 1.png

Monopolistic competition[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

Another possibility: free entry until D is tangent to CM (i.e. until px=CMx) n1 firms and always px>Cmx

Économie internationale rappel concurrence monopolistique 1.png

Gaining trade in monopolistic competition[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

Monopolistic competition models are based on two central assumptions :

  1. Goods are assumed to be differentiated so each firm has a monopoly on its variety.
  2. Each firm considers the prices of its competitors as given.

Gaining trade in monopolistic competition[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

Relationship between price (markup) and number of firms?

  • Symmetrical firms (same cost and demand functions) so they choose the same price, the same quantity produced and represent a 1/n fraction of the total production of the sector.
  • the size of the market is given, so an increase in the number of firms reduces the output of each firm and thus increases its average cost (CC curve)
  • the more firms there are in the sector, the more competition there is and the greater the incentive for firms to reduce their prices (falling markup = PP curve)

Situation initiale[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

Initial situation: Market in autarky with at equilibrium () firms (and therefore varieties) and a price .

Économie internationale rappel monopole et concurrence monopolistique 1.png

Open for business[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

Merger of 2 identical markets of firms

Économie internationale rappel ouverture au commerce 1.png

Gaining trade in monopolistic competition[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

going from (Autarky) to (Free Trade)

Pro-competitive gain

  • markup decreases from math>\mu'</math> to math>\mu</math> and therefore the price decreases from math>p'</math> to math>p</math>.
  • Well-being gains for +C consumers

Gain in economies of scale (or rationalization or selection)

  • Fewer firms operating on the total market (from to ) more production per firm (from to )
  • lower average cost

Gain of varieties

  • Increase the number of varieties available to the consumer from to .
  • Equal gain for producers (more input varieties available => increases their productivity)

Translated with www.DeepL.com/Translator (free version)

Remark[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

Firms disappear when trade is opened up. In this model, as all firms are identical, only chance determines which firms win.

Model with heterogeneous firms: not all firms have the same productivity

Once again, LE has winners and losers: large, highly productive companies win, smaller companies see their market share shrink and disappear.

This type of model also explains why less than 20% of French and American manufacturing companies export, and an even smaller percentage invest abroad.

Empirical evidence?[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

A large part of the trade of OECD countries is intra-industrial (e.g. 40% for the EU). The trade model with economies of scale helps to explain this.

Evolution of the weight of intra-industry trade in world trade. (Source: Marius Brülhart, 2009).

Effect of integration within NAFTA between the US, Canada and Mexico, cf. section 3 chapter 6 in FT (2012) .

Effect of trade integration within the EU-15[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

  • Elimination of tariff barriers (UD in 1968) and especially non-tariff barriers (single market - 1992), then single currency....
  • defragmentation of the European market from 1992 onwards
  • Increased competition

We're getting the effects we expected...

Effect of trade integration within the EU-15 (continued)

Increased competition

  • Gain in variety

Mohler and Seitz (2010): substantial gains between 1999-2008 for small countries (e.g. +0.75% of GDP for Denmark, +2.8% for Estonia), small for large countries.

  • Pro-competitive gain

Allen et al (1999): The implementation of the Single Market reduced price-cost margins by about 4% on average.

  • Gain in economies of scale or rationalisation
  • Increased competition
    • Pressure on profits
    • Economic restructuring

= fewer firms, each of larger size and theoretically more efficient

    • European Competition Surveillance Policy
    • Change in the number of banks in the Euro Zone
    • Mainly due to M&A activity in the euro zone, 77% of which took place within the same country (especially for the largest countries).
Euro area members excluding Cyprus, Estonia, Malta, Slovakia and Slovenia (Sources: Baldwin and Wyplosz 2012).

External economies of scale (or historical accidents versus comparative advantage)[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

External economies of scale[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

According to Marshall, there are 3 main reasons for corporate concentrations (i.e. 3 types of externalities):

  1. Proximity to a large number of specialized suppliers / non-tradable intermediate goods;
  2. Large pool of labor;
  3. Knowledge externalities.

Increasing returns to scale at sector level

Each sector will have a decreasing supply curve: the greater its production, the lower the price at which it is prepared to sell.

Économie internationale économies d’échelle externes illustration 1.png

Historical accidents can have important consequences on the comparative advantage of countries in the presence of external economies of scale,

The presence of external economies of scale may justify ad hoc interventions over time.

Économie internationale économies d’échelle externes illustration 2.png

More importantly. Once it produces at the Thai economy can now satisfy the world economy at a price.

Trade restrictions become a means of promoting exports in these models. With gains to trade at the world level (with Swiss producers suffering losses).

This justification for temporary protection of an industry is known as the infant industry argument.

  • important in the debate on the role of trade policy in the development process, especially in the case of market failures (imperfection in the financial system, ownership problems - see Chapter 8).
  • It is difficult to identify concrete cases of successful industrialisation through import substitution, even though this strategy was widespread in the developing countries in the 1970s.
  • "Trade protection is not enough to develop a comparative advantage and a competitive industry (need to accumulate physical, human capital, etc.)" It is difficult to determine which sectors really need support.

Extension: The Geographic Economy[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

Article détaillé : Economic geography.
Article détaillé : Trade and geographical advantages.

Krugman (Nobel 2008) explains the processes of spatial agglomeration of the economy and the resulting economic exchanges.

Agglomeration dynamics[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

If firms benefit from internal returns to scale and there are transport costs :

  • Interest in being close to a large market...
  • Setting up several companies in the same region
  • Creating external economies of scale" increases the size of the market (new producers attract new workers and therefore new consumers).
  • Attracting new producers ... Cumulative process of spatial agglomeration

Cumulative process of spatial agglomeration resulting from the conjunction of internal and external economies of scale

  • Large regions specializing in industrial goods sectors with increasing returns
  • Peripheral regions specialize in constant-yield production
  • New trade flows

In fact, not all activities with increasing returns are systematically concentrated in a single location because there are forces of dispersion (constraints on worker mobility, congestion effect on immobile factors, intensity of competition).

Krugman (1991): Starting from a situation where industrial sectors with increasing returns to scale are evenly distributed across regions/countries, the lowering of barriers to international trade increases the likelihood of a cumulative process of agglomeration.

Example: European integration[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

Économie internationale exemple intégration européenne 1.png

Countries/regions in the centre of Europe attract and specialise (1/7 of the surface area but 1⁄2 of the activity) + peripheral countries/regions less likely to develop dynamic industrial clusters.

Growing inequalities between European regions.

Ambitious regional policy Necessary to counterbalance the mechanisms of agglomeration.

Trade-off between economic efficiency and spatial equity.

Résumé[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

En présence d’économies d’échelle internes, on aura des produits différenciés et donc de la concurrence imparfaite (on a supposé de la concurrence monopolistique).

Nouveaux gains du commerce:

  • Du coté des consommateurs : le commerce international offre simultanément une plus grande variété de biens à des prix plus faibles
  • Du coté des producteurs: moins de firmes sur le marché qui produisent chacune une plus grande quantité de bien à coût moyen plus faible

Si les économies d’échelle sont externes à la firme (elles ne peuvent pas être internalisées par la firme), l’avantage comparatif peut refléter des accidents historiques. Ceci peut justifier des interventions de politiques ponctuelles.

L’évidence empirique suggère des gains importants de rationalisation ou sélection ainsi que des gains pro-compétitifs sur des marchés qui s’intègrent (exemple de l’UE) .

Annexes[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

References[modifier | modifier le wikicode]