The spread of the Industrial Revolution in continental Europe
Based on a lecture by Michel Oris[1][2]
The Industrial Revolution, a pivotal period in human history, ushered in an era of unprecedented change, marked by a flowering of technological discoveries and radical innovations. Initiated in Great Britain in the twilight of the 18th century, it spread rapidly across the European continent, profoundly reshaping ways of living and working. This era of transition saw the emergence of new production systems, the meteoric expansion of industry and the increasing mechanisation of work processes. In continental Europe, this wave of industrialisation had major repercussions, shaking the economic, social and political foundations of societies.
Technological innovations and the widespread adoption of new production, transport and communication techniques overturned the established order in continental Europe, propelling it from a predominantly rural and agricultural economic structure to a dynamic industrial power. The impact of the Industrial Revolution on the daily lives of Europeans was considerable, redefining the very fabric of social life.
The rise of the Industrial Revolution on the European continent marked the advent of a dazzling economic and social transformation, laying the foundations of our modernity. This era of change gave rise to innovative manufacturing processes, such as steam power, which revolutionised mass production. It spawned the creation of flourishing industrial cities, stimulated the expansion of the bourgeoisie and orchestrated the emergence of an extensive and complex transport and communications network. In all these ways, the Industrial Revolution gave continental Europe the impetus it needed to shape the contemporary capitalist economy.
Industrial development in continental Europe[modifier | modifier le wikicode]
Early pioneers of industrialisation: Belgium, France and Switzerland (1770-1810)[modifier | modifier le wikicode]
At the dawn of the Industrial Revolution, England stood out as a lone pioneer, forging a path in an era dominated by agriculture. The British model of industrialisation was characterised by its polarised nature, based on the robust development of three key sectors: the textile industry, centred mainly on cotton, the booming steel industry and an innovative engineering industry. This industrial boom did not occur uniformly throughout the region, but rather manifested itself in an intense geographical concentration of economic activity. Lancashire, for example, became the beating heart of the textile industry, known for its cotton mills and mass production techniques. At the same time, Birmingham established itself as a centre of metallurgy, where the processing of iron and the production of mechanical tools developed at a frenetic pace. This focus on specific regions not only stimulated the local economy by creating jobs and attracting investment, but also led to the formation of genuine industrial basins, where skills, capital and infrastructure reinforced each other. Through this regional specialisation, England paved the way for an industrial path that the rest of Europe would endeavour to follow, each at its own pace and according to its own specific characteristics.
After England, the industrial revolution began to cross borders, rapidly reaching other European nations, particularly Belgium, France and Switzerland, as well as the United States - whose industrial path deserves a separate analysis. The beginnings of industrialisation in these continental countries emerged barely a decade after England, between 1770 and 1810, and after the Napoleonic Wars, Belgium in particular positioned itself as a serious competitor to England. These countries borrowed heavily from the English model. Transfers of technology and know-how were facilitated by British entrepreneurs and technicians who exported their expertise. In Belgium, John Cockerill is emblematic of this migration of industrial skills; his contribution to the establishment of steel and mechanical engineering industries was fundamental. The Wilkinson brothers played a similar role in France, laying the foundations for future industrialisation. Spurred on by the mercantilist rationale dominant in the 18th century, these countries adopted English innovations to reduce their dependence on foreign countries and stimulate domestic employment. English empirical knowledge, particularly in the field of textiles, needed to be assimilated in the field, through observation and practice. It was against this backdrop that France and Belgium opened their doors to English manufacturers. The textile industry, which required ever more efficient machinery, needed a solid steel industry upstream. In Belgium, it was William Cockerill's son who started the first iron mines, the prelude to a flourishing iron and steel industry. With the extraction of iron, it became imperative to produce sheet metal, which led to the installation of rolling mills. Cockerill didn't stop there; the company went on to create mechanical workshops and eventually produced the first locomotives in Belgium. The direct consequence of these developments was the emergence of industrial complexes on an unprecedented scale, where the entire production process was centralised under the control of a single entrepreneurial entity. This ushered in a new era of complex, integrated industrialisation, propelled by a convergence of skills, innovation and capital, where English knowledge fertilised European soil, giving rise to powerful, self-sufficient industries.
In the wake of the Napoleonic Wars and with the return of peace in 1815, continental Europe resolutely embarked on the road to industrialisation. It was against this backdrop that British workers and technicians, armed with their know-how, crossed the Channel to develop the iron and steel industry on the continent. Their expertise played a pivotal role in the development of this sector outside their native island. The strategies for acquiring precious English industrial knowledge were not limited to the legitimate hiring of experts. Industrial espionage became a tool of choice for nations eager to modernise. Missions were secretly sent to England, where workers and technicians were hired, often with substantial financial backing, to obtain manufacturing and production secrets. One notable example was a French espionage expedition that managed to bribe a Birmingham worker, enabling him to bring back technical knowledge crucial to the manufacture of buttons - an industry that, by its very nature, required precision and technical innovation. These transfers of knowledge were not confined to the acquisition of specific skills; they also encompassed the organisation of work and the division of tasks. By copying these methods, the countries of the continent sought to reproduce the efficiency and productivity that had made British industry so successful. Faced with these practices, a degree of mistrust developed on the British side, giving rise to attempts to protect industrial secrets and maintain Britain's economic supremacy. Nevertheless, the spread of industrial innovations continued, often in the shadow of networks of sociability and connivance that transcended national borders. This process of imitation, adaptation and innovation contributed to the formation of an interconnected European industrial fabric, laying the foundations for a dynamic of growth and exchange that would characterise the Industrial Age.
England, at the height of its industrial power, fiercely protected the secrets of its success. Drastic measures were put in place: it was forbidden to export machine tools and craftsmen with specialised technical skills were required to remain on British soil, thus preventing the dissemination of technical knowledge beyond their borders. However, this isolationist stance began to erode in the 1820s. The British Parliament, in a spirit of economic pragmatism, re-evaluated the benefits of such protectionism. As early as 1824, a paradigm shift began, with British legislators realising the financial benefits of exporting machinery. The British engineering industry, originally conceived as a fortress guarding production secrets, gradually became a player in the international technology trade. It was not until around 1842 that the rigid constraints were significantly relaxed, paving the way for a freer flow of technological innovations and industrial expertise. Mechanisation, the vehicle for this spread of knowledge, accelerated and led to an even more widespread transmission of industrial advances to new countries, particularly in the second half of the 19th century. In countries such as Belgium and France, the development of industrial sectors followed a more linear trajectory than that observed in England. In these countries, development was gradual and coordinated, leading to a more harmonious integration of the various branches of industry, from iron and steel to mechanical engineering and textiles. This sectoral integration fosters effective synergy between the various industries, facilitating sustained economic growth and rapid modernisation. The evolution of UK policies reflects a recognition of the emerging globalisation of the economy and an adjustment to market realities, where maintaining a technological lead requires not only innovation, but also an enlightened international strategy to capitalise on national skills and technologies.
The dynamics of industrialisation in England contrast significantly with those on the European continent, particularly in Belgium and France, in terms of the role of the state and entrepreneurs. In England, the Industrial Revolution was driven by entrepreneurship and private initiative. Economic growth and industrial expansion relied heavily on ingenuity, entrepreneurial risk and private capital. The state plays a facilitating role, mainly by creating a favourable regulatory and legal environment, but it does not intervene directly in industrial affairs. The result was a proliferation of small and medium-sized businesses run by visionary industrialists who, thanks to their ability to innovate and adapt, positioned England as a leader in the industrial revolution. By contrast, Belgium and France took a more dirigiste approach. The Belgian government, aware of the need to stimulate economic growth and technological independence, actively supported industrial development, notably through the creation of the Société Générale de Belgique in 1822. This state-backed financial institution played a crucial role in financing Belgian industrialisation, particularly in the coal, metallurgy and railway sectors. Similarly, in France, the State played a pioneering role in industrialisation. It spurred the creation of the first steelworks, illustrating its active role in the development of a national industrial infrastructure. What's more, the French authorities were not averse to encouraging and even organising industrial espionage in order to transfer British know-how to France, demonstrating a proactive policy in terms of technology transfer. So while the UK relied on entrepreneurial individualism to forge its industrial advance, Belgium and France adopted a more collective approach, with the State acting as a catalyst and guarantor of industrial progress. This difference in approach reflects the cultural and political specificities of the countries concerned, and suggests a variety of models for industrialisation, all of which contributed to the economic transformation of Europe in the 19th century.
Belgium, despite its smaller size and population compared with France, experienced particularly rapid and intense industrialisation during the 19th century. Several factors contributed to this dazzling development. Firstly, Belgium benefited from a geography that was favourable to industrialisation, with abundant coal deposits, essential for energy production at the time, as well as iron deposits that fed its fledgling iron and steel industry. In addition, its central position in Europe facilitated trade and capital flows. Secondly, Belgian industrialisation was strongly encouraged by proactive government policies. As mentioned earlier, the Belgian state supports the infant industry through institutions such as Société Générale de Belgique. This statist approach contrasts with the liberal economic policy of France, where state intervention in the economy is more moderate. Thirdly, Belgium has a social and political cohesion that facilitates investment and the concentration of industrial efforts. The creation of Belgium as an independent nation-state in 1830 gave rise to a nation-building drive that resulted in massive investment in industry and infrastructure, particularly railways. As for France, despite being the most populous country in Western Europe at the time, it experienced a more gradual industrial revolution. France's social and economic structures, in particular the distribution of land ownership and a certain attachment to agricultural traditions, slowed down the transition to industrialisation. In addition, France's political instability in the 19th century, with a succession of monarchical, republican and imperial regimes, may have contributed to a less linear progression of industrialisation. The lightning speed of the industrial revolution in Belgium can be explained by a combination of natural resources, a favourable state policy and a social and political dynamic that created an environment conducive to accelerated industrial development. In France, despite considerable demographic and economic potential, a number of factors slowed down the industrial transition, which took place over a longer timeframe.
Next wave of industrialisation[modifier | modifier le wikicode]
The second wave of industrialisation, which took place in the second half of the 19th century, was characterised by a rapid expansion of industrialisation outside its British and Belgian/French cradles, with countries such as the German Empire and parts of the Austro-Hungarian Empire such as Austria and Bohemia (now the Czech Republic) embracing industrial change. The German Empire, unified in 1871 under Prussia, benefited from a series of factors favourable to rapid and intense industrialisation. These factors included a large and well-educated population, a unified political structure, considerable natural resources (notably coal and iron deposits in the Rhineland and Silesia), and a strong tradition in the scientific and technical fields. What's more, because the industrial revolution started later in Germany than in England, German industrialists were able to adopt tried and tested technologies and benefit from recent innovations, enabling them to catch up quickly. In particular, German industry specialised in the production of capital goods and machinery, sectors in which it would become a world leader. This specialisation is partly explained by the deliberate strategy of German companies and the German government to focus on high value-added products requiring skilled labour and advanced research and development. In the Austro-Hungarian Empire, industrial development was more heterogeneous. Austria and Bohemia, the latter being one of the most advanced industrial regions of the empire, experienced significant industrialisation around the same periods. However, the multinational structure of the Empire led to disparities in development, with some regions remaining predominantly agricultural. The industrialisation of these regions, although it began considerably later than in England, was facilitated by the spread of knowledge and industrial technologies across Europe. The establishment of rail networks and the growth of financial markets also played a key role in providing the infrastructure needed for industrial expansion and mobilising capital for industrial investment. The second wave of industrialisation in Central Europe and Germany followed an accelerated model of development, capitalising on the experience gained by the countries in the first wave and on state policies that encouraged rapid economic growth and specialisation in advanced production sectors.
German industrialisation got off to a later start than its European neighbours, but it caught up remarkably quickly, thanks to a series of favourable conditions. Technicians and entrepreneurs, attracted from Great Britain, France and Belgium, brought with them essential know-how that helped lay the technical and organisational foundations of the emerging industries. Foreign expertise thus served as a catalyst for Germany's industrial expansion. The heavy industry sector, particularly the steel industry, played a decisive role in this development. Rich in natural resources such as coal and iron, the German territories were able to take advantage of this manna to fuel their factories and propel the production of steel and machinery, thus placing themselves at the forefront of industrialisation. The German economy also benefited from significant flows of foreign capital, which financed the creation and development of industrial infrastructure. These financial inflows were attracted by favourable government policies and by the promise of growth in the German market. A decisive factor was the innovative and proactive role of the German banking system. Unlike other models, where banks were reluctant to get involved in industry, German banks actively participated in financing industrialisation. By investing directly in companies and offering strategic advice, they contributed to the effective integration and coordination of industrial development. This unique combination of knowledge transfer, abundant resources, strategic investment and committed banking partnership enabled Germany to transform itself into a major industrial power by the end of the 19th century.
France has positioned itself as an essential pivot in the expansion of the industrial revolution across the European continent, acting as a dynamic driver in the transfer of technology and industrial knowledge. This momentum manifested itself not only in the active dissemination of know-how, but also in the mobilisation of the capital needed for the industrial development of neighbouring nations. The accumulation of wealth by the French, but also by the Belgians, Swiss and British, created a pool of capital available for investment. These financial resources, in search of lucrative returns, naturally found their way to the German regions where the industrial revolution was taking off, fuelling the expansion of businesses and infrastructure across the Rhine. French banking institutions, which already had considerable experience of collecting national savings and channelling them into productive investment, played a crucial role in this dynamic. They were able to draw on their expertise, developed during their own industrial transformation, to finance Germany's industrial emergence. The Paris and London stock exchanges, already well established by this time, provided the necessary platforms for the mobilisation and efficient allocation of capital. The banking system, fortified by the progress made following the Industrial Revolution in these countries, was therefore a key vector in the financing of industrialisation in Germany, propelling the country along the path of rapid and sustained economic growth.
The late arrival of the Industrial Revolution in Germany was something of a strategic advantage, allowing the country to appropriate and benefit directly from the innovations and inventions already developed by its neighbours such as England and France. This immediate access to advanced technology gave a considerable boost to German heavy industry, which became the heart of its industrial development, as opposed to more traditional sectors such as the textile industry. Metallurgy, iron and steel, the chemical industry and the armaments sector became the pillars of Germany's economic transformation, requiring massive long-term capital investment due to the large amount of fixed capital inherent in these industries. The railway, in particular, proved to be a crucial instrument of this transformation, with the construction of thousands of kilometres of track between 1850 and 1870, facilitating the rapid and efficient integration of the national territory and an unprecedented expansion of trade and industry. Germany's wealth of natural resources, particularly Ruhr coal, served as a catalyst for this meteoric industrialisation. German coal production, which was comparable to that of France in 1840, quickly surpassed it and continued to grow exponentially, reaching a level thirteen times higher in 1913. At the dawn of the First World War, Germany dominated world coal production, generating 60% of global output, a statistic that testifies to the speed and scale of its entry into the industrial age.
With a cultural heritage that placed great value on education, Germany already had a remarkably high level of literacy when it began its industrialisation. With only 20% of its adult population illiterate, compared with 44% in England and 46% in France, Germany had a considerable advantage in terms of a potential educated workforce capable of learning new skills quickly. Recognising the crucial importance of education to economic development and industrial competitiveness, the German government set about building a strong education system. Measures were taken to provide not only general education for the entire population, but also and above all a specialised technical training system. These technical and vocational schools were designed to meet the needs of the emerging industry, by training highly skilled workers capable of handling complex machinery and innovating in technical fields. This investment in education and training paid off handsomely, providing German industry with an educated and technically skilled workforce. This not only facilitated the adoption of new technologies, but also contributed to the growth of research and development in Germany, which became a centre of innovation and technical progress throughout the industrial period and beyond.
The dynamism of German industrialisation was also reinforced by forward-looking social policies and a prudent protectionist economic strategy. Otto von Bismarck, Chancellor of the German Empire, was a pioneer in introducing a system of social insurance at the end of the 19th century. This insurance enabled workers to cope with periods of illness and other hazards of life, such as work-related injuries or loss of income due to old age. This social protection not only improved workers' quality of life, but also contributed to social stability by reducing the risks associated with employment in fledgling industries. What's more, by 1890, public sector employment in Germany was higher than in England, and public spending as a proportion of German gross domestic product (GDP) was twice as high as in England. This high level of state involvement in the economy reflected a strategy of industrial development underpinned by protectionist economic policies reintroduced around 1869, following the precepts of Friedrich List's school, which advocated protecting infant industries until they were strong enough to compete on the international market. The alliance between the large landowners and industrialists in Germany bears witness to this caution towards free trade. Both were concerned about foreign competition, particularly cheap wheat imports from the United States, which threatened German agricultural production. These economic and social policies undoubtedly played a key role in Germany's industrial success. By the eve of the First World War, Germany had established itself as Europe's leading industrial power, outperforming its competitors and becoming a model of industrial efficiency and technological progress. By contrast, Austria-Hungary, although part of the same wave of industrialisation, had not followed the same path and was in a much more modest tenth place in terms of industrial development.
Countries industrialised later: Spain, Italy, Russia and Sweden (1860-1890)[modifier | modifier le wikicode]
The industrialisation of peripheral European countries such as Spain, Italy, Sweden and the Russian Empire was later and uneven, reflecting the diversity of economic, social and political conditions across the continent. In Spain, Catalonia became an important industrial centre, particularly for textiles, benefiting from its tradition of trade and its links with other Mediterranean economies. Despite this, Spain as a whole has experienced slow industrialisation, hampered by persistent feudal structures, underdeveloped infrastructure and political unrest. Italy has also experienced fragmented industrialisation, mainly in the north of the country, while the south has remained largely agrarian and less developed. The regions of Piedmont and Lombardy led Italy's industrial boom, with a particular emphasis on the manufacture of textiles, machinery and later the car industry. Sweden, although it began its industrialisation later, benefited from important natural resources such as wood and iron ore, which were essential to its industrial development. Swedish industry flourished particularly in the second half of the 19th century, thanks to innovations in steel production and the expansion of the railways. As for the Russian Empire, despite enormous reserves of raw materials, it was held back by the size of its territory, a serfdom system that was abolished late (in 1861), and a centralised government that was often reluctant to make rapid changes. However, some regions, such as Muscovy and the Baltic region, began to develop industrially, concentrating on textiles, metallurgy and later oil. Industrialisation in these countries was uneven, with pockets of industrial development emerging in specific regions, often in response to the availability of raw materials, entrepreneurial initiative or favourable government policies, rather than a uniform national transformation.
The industrialisation of Russia in the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries marked a significant stage in the country's history, influenced by the need to modernise the economy to support the political and military ambitions of Tsarism. The abolition of serfdom in 1861 by Tsar Alexander II was a crucial step, as it freed peasants from the obligation to serve their feudal lords, paving the way for a workforce for the burgeoning factories and increased mobility of the population. The Russian government also encouraged foreign investment to help finance its industrial development. Railways were a priority, as they were essential for linking Russia's vast territories and for transporting natural resources such as coal and iron ore. French companies in particular were invited to invest in these infrastructure projects, and French capital played a key role in Russian industrial development. The French banking sector has been a major provider of funds for industrial and railway projects in Russia, leading to a strong foreign presence in key sectors of the Russian economy. Foreign investors, attracted by Russia's abundant natural resources and development potential, have taken significant stakes in industries such as textiles, metallurgy and mining. However, this dependence on foreign capital has had long-term repercussions, including a degree of economic vulnerability to external shocks and less control over domestic industrialisation. Despite this foreign investment, Russia remained a largely agrarian economy until the eve of the First World War, and the resulting social and economic tensions contributed to the revolutionary unrest of the early 20th century.
Countries left behind by industrialisation in the 19th century[modifier | modifier le wikicode]
Nineteenth-century industrialisation profoundly transformed parts of the world, but it did not affect all countries in the same way. Some states made a conscious choice not to follow the British model of rapid industrialisation, often because of their own unique economic, social and political conditions. These include the Netherlands, Portugal and Denmark, each of which had a different trajectory during this period. The Netherlands, for example, had already experienced a period of strong economic growth and commercial expansion in the 17th century, known as the Dutch Golden Age. In the nineteenth century, although they did not experience as rapid an industrial revolution as Britain, they concentrated instead on trade and finance, using their vast trading networks and colonial empire to maintain their prosperity. Industry developed later and more gradually. At the time, Portugal was recovering from the effects of the Napoleonic Wars and an economic crisis caused by the loss of its Brazilian colonies. Its peripheral position in Europe, its agrarian economy and its traditional social structures did not encourage rapid industrialisation. In addition, the country was mired in political difficulties, with internal struggles and regime changes hampering economic development. Denmark, on the other hand, had a unique experience. It maintained a largely agricultural economy throughout the 19th century, but gradually improved its agriculture and developed food processing industries that enabled it to prosper. Denmark also invested in education and research, laying the foundations for a more knowledge- and skills-based industrialisation that would accelerate in the twentieth century. In each of these countries, the absence of a rapid industrial revolution such as that which took place in Great Britain was not necessarily synonymous with economic stagnation, but rather with a different path towards economic and social modernity, adapted to their specific conditions and needs.
The former colonies of the Ottoman Empire, such as Albania, Bulgaria, Greece, Romania and the territories that formerly formed Yugoslavia, all underwent complex and often delayed transitions to industrialisation, largely because the structures left behind by the Ottoman Empire were not conducive to the rapid industrial development seen in Western Europe. Albania, which became independent in 1912, faced major internal difficulties and economic obstacles that hampered its industrialisation. The country remained largely agrarian and did not see any major industrial development until the mid-twentieth century. Bulgaria gained autonomy from the Ottoman Empire towards the end of the 19th century, and its path to industrialisation was hampered by regional conflicts and world wars. It was only later, particularly after the Second World War under the Communist regime, that industrialisation was actively pushed forward by the state through nationalisation and economic planning. In Greece, industrialisation was slow to take off after independence in the nineteenth century, with more notable progress at the end of the century and beginning of the twentieth, particularly in textiles, shipbuilding and agri-food, and especially after the First World War. Romania saw a rise in industrialisation towards the end of the 19th century, helped by land reforms and the exploitation of its natural resources such as oil and coal. In particular, the development of the oil industry was a determining factor in the Romanian economy. As for the former Yugoslavia, the region was made up of zones with different levels of industrial development before coming together as a federation after the First World War. Under Communism, after the Second World War, Yugoslavia adopted a model of self-managed socialism which encouraged industrial development in various sectors, including the automotive, steel and chemical industries. Overall, the road to industrialisation in these countries was littered with obstacles such as wars, political changes, accessibility of natural resources, foreign investment and internal politics after independence. The Ottoman past, which tended to leave an economy that was predominantly agricultural and not very industrially advanced, was a major challenge for these nations to catch up with European modernisation.
Poland and Finland within the Russian Empire, Hungary within the Austro-Hungarian Empire, Ireland under British rule and Norway united with Sweden, were territories with the status of internal colonies or integral parts of larger empires. Their path to industrialisation and national sovereignty was unique for each territory, often marked by struggles for autonomy or independence, and influenced by the politics and economics of the reigning empire. Poland, divided between several empires during the 19th century, saw pockets of industrialisation in areas under Prussian or Russian control, with notable industrial development in cities such as Łódź. However, partition and the absence of a sovereign Polish state limited homogeneous and coordinated industrial development. Finland, which was part of the Russian Empire, began to develop industrially at the end of the 19th century, especially after gaining greater autonomy in 1809. This was helped by investment in education and modernisation under the auspices of the Finnish autonomous administration, but always within the framework of Russian economic policy. Hungary, as part of the Austro-Hungarian Empire, experienced an industrial boom, particularly with the Austro-Hungarian Compromise of 1867, which gave Hungary greater economic and political freedom. This led to significant industrial development, particularly in agriculture, but also in steelmaking and mechanical engineering. Ireland, under the yoke of Great Britain, had a very different experience of industrialisation. While regions such as Belfast saw rapid industrialisation, particularly in shipbuilding and textiles, the Great Famine and British policies had a devastating impact on the island, hampering its economic development. Norway, which was united with Sweden until 1905, underwent gradual industrialisation, with the development of industries linked to its natural resources, such as fishing, timber and minerals. The country has also benefited from relatively liberal economic policies and a common market with Sweden, which has encouraged its industrial development. In each of these territories, the paths to industrialisation were strongly influenced by relations with imperial powers, national aspirations, and local economic and political contexts.
Industrialisation in Europe was a transformative process that reshaped not only economies but entire societies. Starting in Britain, the phenomenon spread across the continent in the course of the nineteenth century, ushering in an era of massive urbanisation as waves of people moved from the countryside to the cities, where factories were being built. Occupational profiles underwent an upheaval as the workforce gradually turned away from agriculture to focus on industry and services. The European landscape itself was transformed by the emergence of infrastructure such as railways, canals and roads, facilitating the rapid movement of goods and people. Increased industrial production stimulated economic growth, raising living standards for many people, although these benefits were not evenly distributed across all strata of society. The rise of new social classes, in particular the industrial bourgeoisie and the working class, introduced new social dynamics, often marked by tension and conflict. The impact of industrialisation was not limited to the economic and social spheres; it also permeated culture, thought and ideology, giving rise to new currents such as capitalism, socialism and communism. These far-reaching changes laid the foundations for what is now considered modern industrial civilisation, and paved the way for the complex challenges of the twentieth century, from issues of social justice to those relating to the environment and sustainable resource management.
The theoretical contributions of Alexander Gerschenkron[modifier | modifier le wikicode]
Alexander Gerschenkron has played a crucial role in our understanding of economic development, particularly through his concept of 'economic lag' in industrialisation. According to Gerschenkron, countries that start their industrialisation process late can skip certain technological and organisational stages that the pioneer countries had to go through. This can enable them to catch up quickly, provided certain conditions are met, including strong state involvement to stimulate industrialisation, the development of new financial institutions, and the provision of appropriate technical and vocational education. Gerschenkron highlighted the varied strategies adopted by European countries lagging behind in their industrial development and emphasised that the degree and nature of this lag could influence a country's development path. His ideas have been widely influential and have contributed to a better understanding of the divergent economic trajectories of European nations in the nineteenth and twentieth centuries.
Gerschenkron's theory of economic backwardness provides an explanatory framework for how industrially backward countries were able to catch up with the pioneering countries of industrialisation. He argued that lagging countries had potential advantages in their quest for industrial modernisation because of their ability to adopt advanced technologies and production methods already tried and tested in industrialised countries. In Gerschenkron's view, lagging behind could be an advantage because it pushed for greater technological leaps, thus avoiding the intermediate stages that the pioneer countries had had to go through. This meant that latecomers could set up factories and industrial infrastructures on a large scale, using mass production methods and advanced technologies from the outset, leading to faster industrial growth. From this point of view, the state plays a crucial role as the driving force behind industrialisation, because lagging countries cannot rely on spontaneous market mechanisms to catch up. Instead, they need state intervention to mobilise the necessary resources, including capital and education, to support industrialisation. Gerschenkron pointed out that this acceleration of development often required the creation of banking and financial institutions capable of providing the large amounts of capital needed by advanced and heavy industries. This is why, in countries like Germany, we saw banks playing a leading role in financing industrialisation, whereas in countries like England, industrialisation was more the result of a gradual process financed by more dispersed capital and gradual accumulation. Interestingly, Gerschenkron's theory has been tested and developed in many different contexts, not just in Europe, but also in Asia and Latin America, providing an analytical tool for understanding how and why some countries developed economically faster than others.
Gerschenkron's theory of economic backwardness suggests that countries that start their industrialisation process later tend to start with more advanced, capital-intensive industries, such as the production of producer goods (capital goods) and industrial goods, rather than with basic consumer goods such as textiles, which characterised the early stages of industrialisation in pioneering countries such as Britain. According to this theory, as these later countries enter the industrialisation process with their technological knowledge already established and often more advanced, they can skip intermediate stages and build industries that benefit directly from the latest innovations. This often includes metallurgy and machinery manufacturing, which in turn stimulates the development of other industrial sectors through demand for machinery and infrastructure. In addition, these goods-producing industries have a greater ripple effect on the economy, as they provide the necessary tools for the expansion of other industries. Investment in these capital-intensive sectors tends to be supported by the state or large financial institutions, which is necessary to overcome the lack of initial capital and infrastructure. This is how Germany, which arrived on the industrial scene later than England, was able to become a leader in the fields of steel, chemicals and mechanical engineering, leading to more concentrated and larger-scale industrial development.
The phenomenon of technological 'catch-up' is a central concept in Gerschenkron's theory of economic backwardness and in the study of the history of industrialisation. In England, where the Industrial Revolution began, the first factories and industrial technologies were developed and implemented. Over time, these technologies and factories aged and became less efficient than the new innovations. However, the cost of replacing old equipment and organisational inertia can delay the adoption of newer, more efficient technologies. On the other hand, countries that began industrialising later were not hampered by these early generations of technology and were able to adopt the most advanced technologies directly. This technological leap enabled them to install more modern, more efficient factories from the outset, giving them a competitive advantage in certain industries. This often led to what is known as "latecomer advantage", where industrially backward countries were able to progress more quickly in terms of productivity and industrial capacity, because they did not have to face the same degree of technological obsolescence and could plan their industrial development around the cutting-edge technologies available at the time.
At the start of the Industrial Revolution in England, industrialisation was largely driven by individual entrepreneurs and private investors. The state played a relatively limited role in the direct financing of businesses. However, as industrialisation spread to other countries, particularly those lagging behind technologically and economically, the state and banks began to play increasingly central roles. In the countries that followed England in the industrialisation process, the state often had to take an active role to compensate for the lack of private investment and the weakness of local financial markets. This included the creation of technical education and training institutions to develop a skilled workforce, the construction of infrastructure such as railways, and sometimes the direct financing of strategic industries such as armaments. Banks have also become increasingly important in these lagging economies. The need for capital to finance increasingly complex and costly industries, such as steelmaking and railway construction, led to the creation and expansion of banks capable of providing the large sums needed. In many cases, this was done with the collaboration or direct support of the state, which recognised the importance of industrial development to the country's power and international position. This is consistent with economic theories that recognise the importance of institutions in economic development. A well-developed banking system and strategic state intervention can help overcome barriers to industrial and economic development.
In countries that industrialised later, conditions for workers tend to be more arduous because of the need to catch up quickly with technological and economic progress. These nations have often adopted more intensive production methods to remain competitive, leading to increased work rates and more demanding conditions. The direct use of advanced technologies has imposed a steep learning curve for workers, requiring high skills and rapid adaptation. Pressure is also increasing with the concentration of heavy industry, which requires a great deal of capital and intense labour. Economic transformation is accompanied by massive urbanisation, with workers flocking to the cities in search of work, often generating a surplus of labour that can be exploited, keeping wages low and working hours long. Workers also face difficult living conditions due to rapid urbanisation, which often exceeds the capacity of cities to provide adequate housing and social services. Increased labour market flexibility is another feature, with fewer stable employment contracts and protections for workers, favouring economic adjustment and capital accumulation at the expense of job security. As a result, the demand for better working conditions and social reforms is becoming a pressing issue, both publicly and politically in these countries.
Alexander Gerschenkron has developed a theory according to which industrialisation does not follow a single pattern, but varies considerably from one country to another. According to him, Europe's industrial development has served as a reference for developing countries, but this reference is not a single, invariable model. For example, industrial trajectories have diverged considerably between heavy industry and textiles. Over time, state intervention in the economy and industry has increased, modifying development models. Gerschenkron also pointed out that the delay in industrialisation could offer advantages, such as the possibility of adopting modern technologies at an early stage of industrialisation. However, his theory has been criticised for its inadequate definition of 'backwardness' and for neglecting the human factor and its influence on industrialisation. For example, the sudden interest of British nobles in agronomy contributed to the transition from agriculture to industry. Similarly, the rate of literacy and education, as in the cases of Denmark and Switzerland, where a large proportion of the population could read and write at the end of the 19th century, played a crucial role in the industrialisation of these countries.
Although Gerschenkron's theory of industrialisation is influential, it has been criticised for its shortcomings in defining industrial 'backwardness'. By failing to specify what he means by backwardness, Gerschenkron leaves some ambiguity in his analysis. Critics also point out that his theory does not take sufficient account of the human and social factors that played a role in the industrialisation process. For example, the renewed interest in agronomy among British nobles facilitated the transition from a predominantly agrarian society to an industrial one, by encouraging the movement of labour to urban and industrial centres. Similarly, the rate of literacy and education is a factor that seems to have been underestimated in Gerschenkron's theory. Countries such as Denmark and Switzerland, where the majority of the population was literate by the end of the nineteenth century, illustrate the importance of education as a foundation for industrialisation and economic modernisation. This evidence suggests that industrialisation cannot be fully understood without considering the impact of social and cultural dynamics, as well as the role of education in preparing people to adapt and contribute to the industrial economy.
Origins of the early industrial revolution in Switzerland[modifier | modifier le wikicode]
During the Industrial Revolution, Switzerland distinguished itself by its ability to transcend its geographical challenges and limited natural resources. Thanks to exceptional political and economic stability, the country attracted secure investment and fostered sustained growth. The emphasis on education has produced a highly skilled workforce, well suited to industries requiring precision, such as watchmaking and, later, pharmaceuticals and chemicals. Switzerland specialised in specific sectors where it could excel internationally, notably by focusing on quality rather than quantity. Sophisticated transport and communications infrastructures were developed to overcome the country's physical constraints, strengthening its integration into the global economy. Its status as a global financial centre meant that Switzerland benefited from a constant influx of capital, which was essential for the development of industries requiring substantial investment. The tradition of innovation and a strong entrepreneurial spirit encouraged the creation of competitive companies that sought to expand beyond Switzerland's borders, given the relatively small size of the domestic market. All in all, Switzerland has proved that, despite its initial constraints, a country can position itself advantageously on the global industrial stage by playing to its strengths and promoting quality and innovation.
The Swiss paradox in the face of national obstacles[modifier | modifier le wikicode]
The Swiss paradox lies in its ability to industrialise despite the absence of essential raw materials such as coal, which was considered to be the backbone of the Industrial Revolution. Coal was the primary source of energy to power steam engines and factories, and was also used for heating and generating electricity. Its heaviness and the high costs associated with transporting it represented a serious handicap for a country with no mining resources of its own. Faced with this difficulty, Switzerland developed a number of strategies to compensate. It relied on its comparative advantages, such as its strategic location in Europe, its skilled workforce and its political stability, to attract foreign investment and integrate into the European trade network. Switzerland also invested in improved transport infrastructure, such as railways, to facilitate the import of coal and other raw materials needed for industrialisation. In addition, technical innovation and energy efficiency became priorities, enabling the country to maximise the use of imported resources. In addition, Switzerland focused on industries where the intensity of coal consumption was less critical. It developed highly specialised niche sectors, such as machinery manufacturing, watchmaking and, later, pharmaceuticals and chemicals, where precision and quality of craftsmanship were more important than the abundance of natural resources. Despite the lack of raw materials, Switzerland was able to reinvent itself and find alternative ways of underpinning its industrial development, enabling it to distinguish itself as an internationally competitive industrial power.
Switzerland, with its majestic mountains and lack of coastline, has faced significant challenges to its industrial development. Agriculture was hampered by the lack of large plains, and the absence of access to the sea complicated trade. However, thanks to a series of strategic initiatives, Switzerland was able to flourish as an industrial nation. To overcome these difficulties, Switzerland invested heavily in the development of a dense rail infrastructure that connected it to the main European networks. It has also harnessed its Alpine landscapes to produce hydroelectric power, providing a renewable source of energy that has helped compensate for its lack of coal resources. Political stability and a dynamic market economy have helped to attract foreign investment, consolidating Switzerland's position as a world-renowned financial centre. In addition, it has focused on specialised industries that require more skills than heavy natural resources, such as watchmaking and precision engineering, as well as the chemical and pharmaceutical industries in more recent times. A commitment to education and research has ensured a skilled and innovative workforce. Institutions such as ETH Zurich have become synonymous with excellence in science and technology, further strengthening the country's industrial potential. Despite its geographical disadvantages, Switzerland has demonstrated that a well-conceived and implemented national strategy can turn seemingly insurmountable challenges into springboards for industrial and economic success.
With a modest population of just two million at the start of the 19th century, Switzerland faced the challenge of a small domestic market. Unlike its European neighbours, who had large numbers of consumers to support their industrial production, Switzerland had to find other ways to prosper economically. To overcome this obstacle, Switzerland focused on producing high value-added goods and specialising in sectors requiring advanced skills and precise know-how, such as precision watchmaking, whose products could be exported at a high price to international markets. In addition, Switzerland has developed a competitive financial services sector, attracting capital to invest in innovation and research. Its commitment to free trade and international trade agreements has also given it access to larger markets, compensating for the small size of its domestic market. Switzerland has also capitalised on its reputation for excellence in education and vocational training, ensuring a highly skilled workforce capable of meeting the demands of specialised industries and advanced research. Finally, its strategic location at the heart of Europe has enabled it to make the most of its proximity to other European markets, making it a hub for trade and innovation. The combination of these factors has enabled Switzerland to become a prosperous industrial country, despite the small size of its domestic market.
Switzerland's geography, with no direct access to the sea, could have been a significant brake on trade expansion and integration into the global economy. However, Switzerland has compensated for this by developing an efficient rail and road infrastructure that has linked the country to Europe's main ports and economic centres. Switzerland's central position in Europe has enabled it to become a crossroads for overland transport. In addition, its political neutrality has provided fertile ground for international and financial trade, as well as diplomacy. This situation has facilitated the establishment of stable and long-standing trade relations with neighbouring countries, allowing Swiss goods and services to move more freely despite the absence of a coastline. Innovations in transport and logistics, such as rail tunnels through the Alps, have also opened up vital trade corridors to Italy and other parts of southern Europe. In addition, Switzerland has been able to specialise in areas where dependence on maritime transport is less critical, such as financial services, fine watchmaking, pharmaceuticals and technology. By consolidating its trade relations and taking advantage of its position as a bridge between the cultures and economies of northern and southern Europe, Switzerland has managed to integrate effectively into the global economy despite its landlocked location.
Switzerland's strategic advantages[modifier | modifier le wikicode]
Switzerland has benefited from a number of advantages that have contributed to its industrial success despite the absence of natural resources such as coal or direct access to the sea. Among these advantages, an abundant and relatively healthy workforce played a key role. Because of Switzerland's mountainous environment and pure water sources, Alpine populations generally enjoyed better health than urban and industrial areas where diseases linked to water pollution were common. Low infant mortality and a robust population due to a diet rich in dairy products contributed to an available and resilient workforce. What's more, mountain farming, which was mainly based on livestock rearing, did not require a large workforce, freeing up individuals for the industrial sector. The availability of this workforce, combined with wages that were initially lower than in already industrialised regions, made Switzerland an attractive location for industrial investment, particularly in labour-intensive industries such as watchmaking, textiles and precision engineering. In addition, Switzerland has developed a high-quality education and vocational training system that has produced a skilled workforce, an additional asset for industries requiring specific skills. These factors, combined with a tradition of political stability, innovation and openness to international trade, have enabled Switzerland to compensate for its geographical handicaps and become an industrially advanced country.
Switzerland's high level of literacy was another major asset in its industrial development. At the beginning of the 20th century, a literacy rate of 90% among adults was remarkably high, especially in comparison with other European nations. This advance in education has deep roots in Switzerland's religious and cultural background. The Protestant Reformation, initiated by figures such as Martin Luther and John Calvin, advocated individual reading of the Bible. To make this possible, it was imperative for the faithful to be able to read, which prompted the Protestant regions to promote education and literacy. At the same time, in an effort to retain its faithful and compete with the Protestants, the Catholic Church also encouraged literacy through the Counter-Reformation. The direct consequence of this religious drive for education was the creation of a pool of labour that was not only plentiful, but also skilled. Swiss workers were therefore able to perform complex tasks, fostering the emergence and development of industries requiring a high level of skill and precision, such as instrument making, precision watchmaking, mechanics and pharmaceuticals. This skilled workforce, coupled with a tradition of rigour and quality, has enabled Switzerland to establish itself in highly specialised niche sectors with high added value, thereby compensating for its lack of natural resources and limited domestic market.
The limited availability of agricultural land has often been a driving force behind industrial development in many countries, and Switzerland is no exception. In a context where mountain farming could only provide a limited income, many Swiss turned to proto-industry, which involves the production of goods on a small scale, often in the home or in small workshops, as a complement to their farming activities. This tradition of proto-industry has established a base of skills and technical knowledge among Swiss rural workers. For example, home weaving, watchmaking and other forms of precision craftsmanship developed advanced mechanical and technical skills. When the industrial revolution began to spread across Europe, the Swiss already had the practical experience needed to adapt quickly to industrial machines such as mechanical looms. This relatively easy transition from proto-industry to industrialisation was a key factor in Switzerland's success. It enabled more efficient use to be made of available human resources, transforming partially employed peasants into a productive industrial workforce. As a result, Switzerland was able to integrate rapidly into the new economic paradigm without having to undergo a painful period of transition and workforce training.
The abundance of hydraulic resources in Switzerland compensated for the lack of fossil fuels such as coal, which fuelled the industrial revolution in other regions. Hydropower, drawn from the many rivers and streams flowing out of the Alps, has proved to be a renewable and reliable source of energy for the country. Hydropower played a central role in the industrialisation of Switzerland, providing a clean source of energy to power factories and workshops. It has been particularly important for energy-intensive industries such as chemical production, metallurgy and machinery manufacturing. Water resources also enabled the development of infrastructure such as mills and later dams and hydroelectric power stations, which not only supported industrial activities but also contributed to the country's overall economic development. Switzerland was one of the first countries to adopt hydroelectricity on a large scale, strengthening its competitive edge and ensuring sustained economic growth.
The Swiss decision for a single development path[modifier | modifier le wikicode]
Switzerland adopted an ingenious export strategy to overcome the limited size of its domestic market, concentrating on producing high-quality goods for international markets. In the 1830s, for example, Switzerland exported an average of $18 worth of goods per capita each year, well above the UK's $10, Belgium's $7 and the European average of $3. This approach has enabled Switzerland to become competitive in key sectors despite its initial geographical disadvantages. Switzerland has distinguished itself by specialising in specific niches where quality and precision are paramount, such as watchmaking, where it is recognised worldwide for its excellence. This has required constant investment in innovation and the training of a highly qualified workforce. In addition, Switzerland has built a global reputation for its products, a crucial factor in the pharmaceutical, precision machinery and medical equipment sectors, consolidating its position as a leader in these industries on an international scale.
Switzerland opted for a strategy of high specialisation in the textile sector, focusing on market niches where it could offer distinct added value. Instead of competing directly with England in the mass textile market, Switzerland focused on the production of luxury textiles such as silk and high-quality embroidered fabrics. This strategic choice has enabled it to stand out on the international market, despite its small population and geographical constraints. By positioning itself in less crowded and more lucrative market segments, Switzerland has been able to achieve sufficient profit margins to stimulate its economic development without the need for massive sales volumes. Success in these specialist niches helped establish Switzerland's reputation for innovation and quality, strengths that continue to underpin its economy today.
Switzerland has also excelled in watchmaking, becoming synonymous with precision and luxury in the sector. Watchmaking requires few raw materials in terms of volume, but demands a high level of skill and specialisation, which has enabled Switzerland to build a thriving watch industry. By focusing on high value-added production, the Swiss watch industry has been able to offset the cost of importing the necessary materials, such as steel. The expertise and specialisation of the Swiss workforce in watchmaking not only increased the value of the finished products, but also helped to justify the high international selling prices. These watches are not simply instruments for measuring time; they have become symbols of status and luxury, reinforcing the "Swiss Made" quality mark. The combination of a skilled workforce, constant innovation and a focus on the top end of the market enabled Switzerland to become a world leader in the watchmaking sector, a status it firmly maintains to this day.
The initial phases of the industrial boom[modifier | modifier le wikicode]
The start of industrialisation in Switzerland's textile sector was marked by the spinning stage, between 1800 and 1820. Faced with a shortage of coal to power the traditional textile machines being developed in England, Switzerland had to adapt its production organisation by exploiting its water resources to power the spinning machines. During this period, the Swiss also sought to distinguish themselves from the mass-produced textiles from England. They turned to dyeing, a process that not only embellished textiles but also gave them a unique character. By emphasising quality and aesthetics, Swiss textiles were able to attract customers who were prepared to pay more for products that were considered more attractive and rare. This approach enabled Switzerland to develop a niche in the international textile market, specialising in products with higher added value. This was all the more important given that, unlike nations with large domestic markets, Switzerland had to rely on exports to ensure the success of its industries. By focusing on quality and innovation in the processing of its textiles, Switzerland succeeded in establishing a reputation for excellence in this specific area of the textile industry.
Switzerland's expansion in metallurgy can be attributed to a convergence of technical innovations and commercial opportunities. With the growth of the railway network in the mid-nineteenth century, Switzerland was able to take advantage of the surplus steel production of its Belgian and French neighbours, which stimulated the development of its own metal industry. The introduction of machine tools marked a significant turning point, enabling the transition from small-scale production to mechanised production, characterised by greater precision and specialisation. This gave rise to a competitive manufacturing industry, capable of producing complex metal parts for a variety of industrial applications. At the same time, Switzerland capitalised on the skills it had acquired in textile dyeing to venture into the chemical industry. The combination of skills in machinery and chemical processing paved the way for innovation in dyes, medicines and other specialised chemicals. In addition, mastery of chemistry laid the foundations for the development of the food and pharmaceutical industries in Switzerland. The food industry has benefited from advances in food preservation and processing, while the pharmaceutical sector has progressed thanks to Switzerland's ability to produce quality medicines. The shift to metallurgy and chemicals was therefore a natural step for the Swiss economy, built on a tradition of precision craftsmanship and a tendency towards innovation. This enabled Switzerland not only to make up for its shortfall in natural resources, but also to establish itself as an industrial force with world-renowned companies in these sectors.
Swiss industrialisation was more gradual and spread out over time, taking around a century to consolidate. This slower pace, compared with that of its European neighbours such as France and Belgium, can be explained by a number of factors, including the lack of directly available natural resources and geographical constraints. Despite these challenges, Switzerland has been able to capitalise on its unique strengths, such as its skilled workforce and innovation in niche industries like watchmaking, precision equipment, chemicals and pharmaceuticals. The Swiss approach emphasised quality and specialisation over quantity. In 1910, Switzerland exported an average of $60 per capita per year, an impressive figure when compared with the European average of $18 per capita per year. This relative success is a good illustration of Switzerland's industrialisation strategy, which focused on the production of high value-added goods. This has enabled Switzerland to maximise the economic benefits of its exports despite a lower overall production volume. This remarkable export performance can be partly explained by the upmarket positioning of Swiss products on the world market. By focusing on luxury or technically advanced products, Switzerland was able to secure high margins, which compensated for its small domestic market and its limitations in terms of mass production.
Switzerland before the Great War: distinctive features and major achievements[modifier | modifier le wikicode]
As the First World War approached, Switzerland stood out for its advanced economic development and relative prosperity. Gross domestic product per capita in Switzerland reached $895, well above the European average of $550 a year, a clear indicator of the wealth that the Swiss economy was capable of generating for its residents. This was partly due to an industrialisation that had taken a highly specialised direction, focusing on industries requiring cutting-edge skills and producing high value-added goods, such as watchmaking and pharmaceuticals. The international reputation of Swiss products was strongly associated with innovation and quality, enabling the country to assert itself on world markets despite its limited domestic market. This was reinforced by political stability and a policy of neutrality that attracted investment and made Switzerland a reliable financial centre for international capital. The country also benefited from an education system that had created a well-educated and skilled population capable of meeting the demands of advanced industrial sectors. And although it had no direct access to the sea, Switzerland had developed an efficient transport network, including railways across the Alps, enabling it to maintain strong trade links with the rest of Europe. The strength of Swiss exports per capita underlined the competitiveness of domestic products on international markets. Finally, Switzerland's position as a major financial centre was not insignificant, with financial services renowned for their quality, confidentiality and security, attracting substantial international investment. All these factors played a part in establishing Switzerland as an exceptionally prosperous economy before the global upheaval caused by the First World War.
On the eve of the First World War, Geneva was remarkably cosmopolitan, with almost half its population made up of foreigners. In 1910, immigrants, mainly from Germany and Italy, made up 42% of the city's inhabitants, a figure that almost a century later, in 2005, was still significant at 38%. This high proportion of foreigners in Geneva's population reflects not only Switzerland's attractiveness as an economic and financial centre, but also its long and rich history as a land of welcome for political refugees, skilled workers and intellectuals. The presence of such diversity has certainly contributed to Geneva's economic and cultural dynamism, with the city becoming a crossroads for international exchanges and a melting pot of skills and talents from all over Europe. This mix of populations has also influenced Swiss immigration and naturalisation policy, which is often seen as a model of integration, and has shaped Switzerland's reputation as a place of tolerance and cultural diversity.
From the beginning of the 20th century, Switzerland was characterised by its resolutely international orientation, a necessity dictated by the small size of its domestic market and its desire to broaden its economic horizons. This extraversion manifested itself not only through a vigorous export policy but also through significant investment of Swiss capital abroad. Switzerland proved to be a forerunner in the establishment of companies of international stature. Companies such as Nestlé and Basel-based pharmaceutical giants like Sulzer had already achieved multinational status by 1910, with administrative headquarters in Switzerland but production operations spread across Europe and beyond. This strategy enabled them to minimise the risks associated with fluctuations in local markets and to capitalise on competitive advantages specific to different regions, such as labour costs, natural resources and technological skills. In this way, Switzerland established itself as an influential economic player on the world stage, not only as an exporter of high-quality products, but also as a shrewd investor and an innovator in the management and organisation of businesses on a global scale. This drive towards extroversion laid the foundations for Switzerland's international reputation as a global financial centre and home to major multinationals in industry and services.
At the dawn of the First World War, Switzerland's demographic landscape was characterised by a relatively modest level of urbanisation, particularly when compared with European averages at the time. While more than half the population of Europe lived in urban areas, in Switzerland the figure was around 37%. This can largely be explained by the country's topography, dominated by the Alps, which restricted the space available for urban expansion. In 1910, none of them had a population in excess of 200,000. The country's industrialisation had taken a distinctive form, spreading diffusely across the territory rather than being concentrated in vast industrial complexes. This dispersal of industrial activity is partly attributable to the nature of the industries that developed in Switzerland - often specialised, high-tech and high value-added, not necessarily requiring the concentration of workers and services that heavy industries required. This structure has enabled Switzerland to preserve a certain quality of life and avoid the social and environmental problems frequently associated with rapid, massive urbanisation. Switzerland's industrial and demographic configuration has thus played a role in shaping its modern society, contributing to its economic development while preserving its natural landscapes and living environment.
Development issues for small European nations[modifier | modifier le wikicode]
The Industrial Revolution had a diverse impact across Europe, and small countries often followed development paths that reflected their unique local conditions, available resources and relationships with the emerging industrial powers of the time, such as England. Portugal and Denmark are two interesting examples of this dynamic. Portugal, with its close historical links to Britain through the Methuen Treaty of 1703, saw its economy remain largely agricultural during the Industrial Revolution, becoming a supplier of wine and agricultural products to Britain and its colonies. Portugal was also a market for British textiles and other manufactured goods. Industrial development in Portugal was therefore slow and limited, partly because of this economic dependence and also because of political instability, underdeveloped infrastructure and emigration. Denmark, on the other hand, took a different path. Agriculture there was highly developed and innovative, with a strong emphasis on cooperation and improved farming methods, which enabled a relatively smooth transition to high value-added forms of commercial farming and dairy and pig production. Indeed, Denmark has become a major exporter of food products to British and German industrial markets. At the same time, it has developed a food processing industry and a competitive merchant fleet. Education and workforce training have also been priorities, providing a skilled workforce capable of supporting industrial and commercial development. These countries have shown that economic success during and after the Industrial Revolution did not depend solely on heavy industrialisation, but could also be achieved through strategies tailored to local resources and skills. By focusing on sectors where they had a comparative advantage, these nations were able to forge sustainable economic niches in the global context of the time.
David Ricardo's theory of comparative advantage is fundamental to understanding the dynamics of international trade and economic development, especially during the Industrial Revolution. According to this theory, even if a country is less efficient in the production of all goods than another country, there is always a gain in specialising in the production of goods in which it has a lesser comparative disadvantage. By specialising and trading, countries can increase their overall production and benefit from the consumption of goods produced more efficiently by others. For small countries like Portugal and Denmark, this means that they can concentrate on sectors where they can produce more efficiently than other nations, even if they are not the absolute best in those sectors. For Portugal, this meant concentrating on agriculture and wine production, where they had an advantageous climate and historical know-how. For Denmark, it meant a focus on high-quality agricultural production and food processing. This approach also has modern implications. In a globalised world, where production can be distributed through international supply chains, a country's ability to focus on its comparative advantages is more important than ever. It allows smaller economies to compete in the global marketplace, providing specialised products or services that complement larger, more diversified economies.
This theory shows that even if a country is not the most efficient in the production of any good (i.e. it has no absolute advantage), there are benefits in specialising in the production of goods in which it has the greatest relative advantage, or the least relative disadvantage, and trading these goods with other countries. Country A has a comparative disadvantage in the production of good y because it has to sacrifice more good x to produce one unit of y compared with country B. So it makes sense for country A to specialise in the production of x, where it has a smaller disadvantage, and for country B to specialise in the production of y. Specialisation and trade based on comparative advantage enable both countries to improve their economic well-being. They can both consume more goods than they could by remaining in autarky (economic isolation), because trade gives them access to a greater quantity of the goods produced by the other country at a lower cost than domestic production. This theory is a fundamental pillar of free trade and is used to argue in favour of reducing trade barriers between countries, thereby enabling a more efficient allocation of resources on a global scale and increasing global production and consumption.
Portugal as a case study: economic complementarity and persistent poverty[modifier | modifier le wikicode]
The Treaty of Methuen (also known as the Treaty of Baskets) was a good illustration of the idea of comparative advantage even before David Ricardo formalised the theory. Signed in 1703 between England and Portugal, the treaty stipulated that Portuguese wines would be admitted to the English market at lower tariffs than French wines, while English textiles would be admitted to Portugal without restrictions. The result of this treaty was that Portugal specialised in the production of wine, a sector where it had a comparative advantage, while England specialised in the production of textiles, where it had a comparative advantage. This allowed both countries to benefit from mutually advantageous trade. However, modern analysis suggests that the Treaty of Methuen was not necessarily advantageous for Portugal's long-term economic development. Indeed, it may have helped to concentrate the Portuguese economy on agriculture and discouraged industrialisation, which may have held back the country's economic development compared with England, which continued to industrialise and innovate. Ricardo built his theory of comparative advantage on the idea that even if a country is less efficient in the production of all goods, it should concentrate on the production and export of goods in which it is relatively more efficient. This should lead to a situation where all countries can gain from trade, as each economy focuses on its relative strengths. The 'perfect world' of which Ricardo speaks is a theoretical state where all countries would benefit from specialisation and unfettered free trade. In practice, of course, many other factors come into play that can prevent the realisation of this ideal, such as trade barriers, differences in technology and the mobility of factors of production, domestic political issues, and imbalances of economic and political power between nations.
The Treaty of Methuen established a kind of asymmetrical trading partnership between Portugal and England, focusing on free trade in specific products where both countries felt competitive. The agreement was signed in a context where the national economies were seeking to maximise their advantages in international trade. On the British side, the wool (and wider textile) industry was booming and represented a key sector of the economy. Tax-free access to the Portuguese market offered a considerable advantage to English producers and encouraged the expansion of this industry. As for Portugal, its wine, particularly Port wine, enjoyed a high reputation and could be exported to England without encountering the prohibitive taxes often applied to foreign wines, particularly French, which were the main competitors at the time. However, the treaty also had long-term effects that were not entirely beneficial for Portugal. By opening its market to British textiles, Portugal sacrificed the development of its own industrial capacity. While England industrialised, Portugal remained largely agrarian. This imbalance was later criticised as having hindered the diversification and industrialisation of the Portuguese economy. Applying Ricardo's logic, the treaty appears to be a perfect application of the theory of comparative advantage. However, Portugal's complex economic history suggests that long-term dependence on agreements of this kind can have undesirable consequences if not balanced by domestic policies to promote economic diversification and industrialisation.
The Methuen Treaty has had a profound impact on Portugal's economic development. The trade agreement, while seemingly mutually beneficial in the short term, had long-term repercussions that were not symmetrical. The dynamics of the treaty strengthened England's position as an emerging industrial power, as it had already begun its industrial revolution. Indeed, manufactured goods such as textiles were more highly valued on international markets and led to greater capital accumulation than agricultural products. For Portugal, the situation was the opposite. The Treaty encouraged Portugal to concentrate on wine production, which was less likely to encourage a process of autonomous industrialisation. Portuguese entrepreneurs who could have initiated local industrialisation found themselves in direct competition with more advanced and less expensive British products, a competition they could not win due to the absence of import taxes that could have protected their fledgling industries. The effect of this dynamic was to keep the Portuguese economy in a predominantly agrarian state and hindered its industrial development, contributing to an economic lag behind nations that had industrialised. The treaty illustrates how the theory of comparative advantage, in practice, can lead to unexpected or harmful results, particularly when trade is unbalanced and there are no accompanying measures to promote industrialisation and economic modernisation.
Brazil's independence in 1822 significantly disrupted Portugal's economy, because prior to that date, Brazil represented not only a major outlet for Portuguese manufactured goods, but also a vital source of income through its exports of colonial products. After the separation, Brazil broadened its commercial horizons and reduced its imports from Portugal in favour of other nations, often offering more attractive tariffs. This loss exacerbated Portugal's economic dependence on England, already firmly entrenched after the signing of the Treaty of Methuen in 1703. Portugal, which specialised in the production of wine for export, mainly port wine, which was very popular in England, found itself in a precarious situation when English tastes turned to French wines in the second half of the 19th century. The situation worsened as demand for Port declined. Without economic diversification and limited industrialisation, Portugal suffered significant economic vulnerability. Fluctuations in demand for its main export product and changes in the trade policies of partner countries, mainly England, had a direct impact on the Portuguese economy. At the start of the twentieth century, living standards in Portugal were among the lowest in Europe, with GDP per capita of just $400 in 1910, well below the European average at the time. This contrasted sharply with the prosperity of Europe's industrial nations, where living standards were much higher thanks to more diversified industrialisation and more balanced foreign trade. Dependence on a single export product and vulnerability to changes in the preferences of trading partners therefore hampered Portugal's economic development, underlining the importance of economic diversification for long-term stability and growth.
Denmark as a counter-example: beneficial complementarity and economic prosperity[modifier | modifier le wikicode]
The industrialisation of England in the 19th century led to a significant increase in its cereal imports, benefiting countries such as Denmark, which became key exporters to the English market thanks to trade agreements such as free trade treaties. In the first half of the 19th century, Denmark benefited from this agreement by supplying grain to England, consolidating a favourable trading relationship. However, the massive arrival of American wheat in Europe in the 1870s triggered a major agricultural crisis, profoundly affecting countries whose economies were heavily dependent on agriculture. Faced with this crisis and reduced demand for its cereals, Denmark showed great resilience by restructuring its agricultural economy. Instead of collapsing under the weight of competition and remaining in an increasingly unprofitable agricultural sector, Denmark redirected its production towards livestock farming and the production of high value-added foodstuffs such as dairy products, bacon and eggs. These products corresponded perfectly to British eating habits, particularly for their traditional breakfast. By specialising in these new areas, Denmark not only maintained, but strengthened its economic relationship with England. This adaptation has enabled Denmark to convert a dependency that could have become negative, like that of Portugal, into a positive one, taking advantage of a secure and profitable export market. Denmark's ability to adapt and reinvent itself in the context of a changing global economy has enabled it to remain economically viable and to maintain a relatively high standard of living for its population.
Denmark's successful economic conversion during the agricultural crisis at the end of the 19th century was based on two decisive aspects. Firstly, the farming population was well educated, which enabled it to understand quickly and adapt effectively to the new global economic challenges, particularly competition from American wheat. This education played a key role in facilitating the transition to more sophisticated breeding and dairy production methods. On the other hand, the Danish government has implemented an appropriate economic and social policy, recognising the challenges imposed by changing global trade dynamics. Government support has taken the form of favourable land reforms, investment in agricultural training and the encouragement of cooperation between farmers, particularly through dairy cooperatives. This support has contributed to better marketing and standardisation of the quality of agricultural products. By combining these efforts, Denmark has not only overcome the agricultural crisis by diversifying its economy towards livestock and dairy production, but has also maintained a high standard of living for its population.
The agricultural crisis caused by the massive arrival of American cereals in Europe led to a devaluation of farmland in Denmark, a country that had previously been heavily dependent on wheat exports to England. Faced with this situation, the Danish government adopted a proactive strategy by buying up the farmland owned by the king and nobles, the value of which had fallen considerably as a result of the decline in farm incomes. Once this land had been acquired, the government redistributed it to the peasants, enabling them to become the owners of the land they farmed. The aim was twofold: to encourage productive agriculture by giving farmers direct access to the benefits of their labour, and to break feudal dependence and stimulate individual initiative. Land reform has enabled farmers to benefit fully from the fruits of their labour, eliminating the intermediaries who were capturing a significant proportion of the profits. This increased economic independence motivated farmers to adopt more efficient production methods and to turn to more profitable sectors, such as livestock and dairy production, which were in strong demand on the British market. These reforms have played a central role in transforming Denmark into a modern, diversified agricultural economy, capable of meeting the challenges posed by changes in international markets. By becoming owners of their land, Danish farmers have been able to invest in improving their production and, with the support of the government, have succeeded in placing Denmark among Europe's leaders in agriculture and food production.
The Danish government has taken innovative measures to support and modernise agriculture in the face of the challenges posed by cheap American grain imports. One of these measures was to organise farmers into cooperatives. The idea behind cooperatives is to pool the resources and efforts of individual farmers to achieve objectives that they could not achieve alone. Family farms, while retaining their autonomy, have benefited from the collective strength of participating in producers' cooperatives. This enabled them to invest in expensive equipment and advanced technologies, such as milking machines and pasteurisation equipment. Co-operatives also made it possible to better structure the distribution and sale of agricultural products, improving market access and logistical efficiency. By sharing investment costs and collaborating on the purchase of equipment, farmers could not only improve the productivity and quality of their products, but also strengthen their bargaining power on the market. This led to greater standardisation and improved competitiveness for Danish products on international markets, particularly in the UK, where demand for processed agricultural products such as dairy and pork was high. These initiatives, combined with a well-trained agricultural workforce and constant government support, transformed Danish agriculture and enabled the country to overcome the agricultural crisis of the 19th century, positioning it as a major exporter of high-quality agri-food products.
During the years of economic depression between 1873 and 1890, Denmark took proactive measures to mitigate the consequences of the agricultural crisis and help the population adapt to structural changes in the economy. By introducing unemployment insurance in 1886, the Danish state sought to provide a safety net for workers, and in particular farmers, who faced economic uncertainty during the period of transition from an agriculture centred on cereal production to one specialising in livestock farming. Old-age insurance was also introduced to look after elderly farmers. The government recognised that retraining was not a realistic option for this section of the population due to their advanced age. By offering them financial support, the State ensured that these elderly people were not left destitute and could live with dignity despite the rapid changes in the agricultural economy. These innovative social policies not only provided immediate help to those affected by the recession, but also helped to stabilise the economy by maintaining people's purchasing power and stimulating domestic demand. These measures also had the side-effect of strengthening the social fabric and preventing the economic and social distress that could have resulted from a period of mass unemployment and poverty among ageing rural populations.
In 1913, the average annual income of a Danish citizen was $885, well above the European average of $550 a year. This relative prosperity reflects Denmark's success in transforming its agricultural economy in the face of the challenges posed by international competition and changing market demands. The transition to an economy based on dairy production and other livestock products for export has enabled Denmark to maintain a high standard of living for its citizens, thanks in particular to a strategy of educating farmers, a government policy supporting the economy and the establishment of efficient agricultural cooperative structures.