« Economic geography: approaches and challenges » : différence entre les versions

De Baripedia
(Page créée avec « L’histoire des échanges s’inscrit dans une histoire longue de la mondialisation à partir du XVème siècle. Nous n’allons pas uniquement parler de l’économie de... »)
 
Aucun résumé des modifications
 
(8 versions intermédiaires par le même utilisateur non affichées)
Ligne 1 : Ligne 1 :
L’histoire des échanges s’inscrit dans une histoire longue de la mondialisation à partir du XVème siècle. Nous n’allons pas uniquement parler de l’économie de marché, une part de l’économie n’est pas régulée par le marché. Les économistes et parfois la géographie économique sont obnubilés par le marché. Dans notre vie quotidienne, une énorme part la de la production, de la consommation et de l’échange économique est régulée autrement que par le marché. L’accent va beaucoup être mis sur les formes de régulation de l’économie qui ne sont pas celles de l’économie de marché à savoir le don contre don et la redistribution. L’économie est encastrée dans du social et culturel et souvent les comportements économiques s’expliquent par des facteurs qui sont autres qu’économique, l’explication peut être à l’extérieur de l’économie.
{{Infobox Lecture
| image =
| image_caption =
| faculté =
| département =
| professeurs = [[Jean-François Staszak|Staszak, Jean-François]]<ref>Jean-François Staszak. Wikipédia, l'encyclopédie libre.  http://fr.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=Jean-Fran%C3%A7ois_Staszak</ref><ref>[https://www.unige.ch/sciences-societe/geo/membres/enseignants/staszakjeanfrancois/ Page personnelle de Jean-François Staszak sur le site de l'Université de Genève]</ref><ref>[[https://www.franceculture.fr/personne/jean-francois-staszak Publications de Jean-François Staszak sur le site de France Culture]]</ref><ref>[https://www.cairn.info/publications-de-Staszak-Jean-Fran%C3%A7ois--2057.htm Publications de Jean-François Staszak diffusées sur Cairn.info ]</ref><ref>[http://unige.academia.edu/JeanFran%C3%A7oisStaszak Page de Jean-François Staszak sur Academia.edu]</ref><ref>[https://www.babelio.com/auteur/Jean-Francois-Staszak/322744 Biographie de Jean-François Staszak sur Babelio.com]</ref><ref>[http://www.liberation.fr/auteur/13553-jean-francois-staszak Publication de Jean-François Staszak sur Liberation.fr]</ref>
| assistants = 
| enregistrement =
| cours = [[Economic geography]]
| lectures =
*[[Economic geography: approaches and challenges]]
*[[The circuits and their geographies]]
*[[Trade and geographical advantages]]
*[[Geography of wealth and development]]
*[[Geography of the Film Industry]]
}}


Un certain nombre de théories vont être abordé comme la théorie de l’ouverture des circuits économiques, la géographie des avantages comparatifs et des rendements croissants, les inégalités spatiales de développement ou encore la question environnementale. La géographie économique est parfois réduite à une description du monde, nous allons développer une approche culturelle qui est un courant de la géographie économique depuis une quinzaine d’années.
The history of trade is part of a long history of globalization from the 15th century. We are not just going to talk about the market economy, a part of the economy is not regulated by the market. Economists and sometimes economic geography are obsessed with the market. In our daily lives, a huge part of production, consumption and economic exchange is regulated other than by the market. Much emphasis will be placed on the forms of regulation of the economy that are not those of the market economy, i.e. donation for donation and redistribution. The economy is embedded in social and cultural and often economic behaviours are explained by factors that are other than economic, the explanation may be outside the economy.


= Qu’est-ce que la géographie économique ? =
A certain number of theories will be tackled such as the theory of the opening up of economic circuits, the geography of comparative advantages and increasing returns, spatial inequalities in development or the environmental question. Economic geography is sometimes reduced to a description of the world, we will develop a cultural approach that is a current of economic geography for fifteen years.


== Définition par les disciplines ==
{{Translations
| fr = La géographie économique : approches et enjeux
| es = Geografía Económica: Enfoques y Temas
| it = Geografia economica: approcci e sfide
}}


Il y a plusieurs façons de définir la géographie économique. Une première façon est d’inscrire la géographie économique au croisement de deux disciplines avec d’un côté la géographie et de l’autre l’économie. Néanmoins, il existe des définitions canoniques :
= What is economic geography? =
*la géographie est une science qui s’intéresse à l’organisation de l’espace à la dimension spéciale de sociétés. C’est une science sociale qui porte sur l’espace et son organisation.
*l’économie est une science qui porte sur la production, la circulation et la consommation des biens rares.


Comment peut-on croiser la géographie économique, la production et la consommation des biens rares ainsi que la question de l’organisation de l’espace ?
== Definition by disciplines ==


== Définition par l’objet ==
There are several ways to define economic geography. One way is to place economic geography at the crossroads of two disciplines with geography on one side and economics on the other. Nevertheless, there are canonical definitions:
* Geography is a science that is interested in the organization of space to the special dimension of societies. It is a social science that deals with space and its organization.
* Economics is a science that deals with the production, circulation and consumption of rare goods.
How can we cross economic geography, production and consumption of rare goods as well as the question of the organization of space?


La géographie à un objet, c’est une géographie de l’économique. Il existe de l’économique, de la production, la consommation, l’échange des biens rares et nous allons en faire une géographie en nous intéressant à la dimension spatiale de l’économique comment est organisée la dimension spatiale de l’économie, c’est-à-dire où se fait la production, où se fait la consommation, par où passe l’échange des biens rares. C’est localiser l’économique, la production, la consommation et l’échange.
== Definition by object ==


À la question de la géographie économique, il y a des explications très variées :
Geography has an object, it is a geography of economics. There is economics, production, consumption, the exchange of rare goods, and we are going to make a geography of it by looking at the spatial dimension of economics, how the spatial dimension of the economy is organized, that is, where production takes place, where consumption takes place, through which the exchange of rare goods takes place. It means locating economics, production, consumption and trade.
*économiques orthodoxes ;
*économiques hétérodoxes : néo-marxisme, école des conventions ;
*non économique : anthropologie, sociologie économique ;
*tournant culturel de la géographie économique : c’est faire attention aux éléments culturels.


La géographie économique est une géographie du monde économique.
When it comes to economic geography, there are very varied explanations:
*orthodox economics ;
*economic heterodox: neo-Marxism, school of conventions ;
*non-economic: anthropology, economic sociology ;
*cultural turning point in economic geography: paying attention to cultural elements.


== Définition par l’approche ==
Economic geography is a geography of the economic world.


La géographie économique serait faire de la géographie par l’économie, c’est-à-dire adopter un raisonnement économique, expliquer des faits géographiques en faisant appel à des raisonnements économiques. C’est faire une interprétation économique de la géographie en utilisant des théories économiques pour expliquer des faits géographiques. Va être emprunté à l’économique le modèle de l’homo oeconomicus et essayer de voir quelles sont les lois de son comportement spatial.
== Definition by approach ==


L’homo oeconomicus a un comportement en termes d’offre, de demande, mais aussi un comportement spatial. Ce comportement peut être modélisé et quantifié faisant qu’il est possible d’en étudier les conséquences en faisant l’agrégation des comportements individuels. Dans un espace homogène peuplé par des homo oeconomicus qui tous suivent les lois de la rationalité, pleinement informées, égoïstes tendant à maximiser leur profit, leur choix spatiaux, où ils habitent, produisent, consomment vont suivre certaines lois et que de ces lois vont émerger des structures spatiales. La géographie économique, en étudiant l’homo oeconomicus, va voir comment les comportements spatiaux des êtres humains résultent de grandes formes d’organisations spatiales. Ce sont des expériences de l’esprit, à savoir des modèles économiques, dont on essaie de voir les composantes spatiales.
Economic geography would be geography through economics, that is, adopting economic reasoning, explaining geographical facts using economic reasoning. It is making an economic interpretation of geography by using economic theories to explain geographical facts. Will be borrowed from the economic model of homo oeconomicus and try to see what are the laws of its spatial behavior.


Trois grandes questions vont être posées :
Homo oeconomicus behaves in terms of supply and demand, but also in space. This behaviour can be modelled and quantified so that its consequences can be studied by aggregating individual behaviours. In a homogeneous space populated by homo oeconomicus who all follow the laws of rationality, fully informed, selfish tending to maximize their profit, their spatial choices, where they live, produce, consume will follow certain laws and that these laws will emerge spatial structures. Economic geography, by studying homo oeconomicus, will see how the spatial behaviours of human beings result from large forms of spatial organizations. They are experiments of the mind, namely economic models, whose spatial components we try to see.
*question de la localisation – économie spatiale – Von Thünen, Weber, Christaller : peut-on modéliser la localisation des activés agricoles, industrielles et des services ? En théorie, en s’appuyant sur le raisonnement et le comportement rationnel et pleinement informé de l’homo oeconomicus, on peut vérifier les modèles de Von Thünen, Weber ainsi que de Christaller.
*Les théories des échanges – économie internationale – Ricardo : les économistes réfléchissent beaucoup sur les échanges, mais bien souvent ils ne mettent pas l’accent sur la dimension spatiale de ces échanges. Ces théories vont s’interroger sur le sens des échanges et les structures spatiales qui vont résulter de ces échanges. Avec Ricardo, il va en résulter une spécialisation.
*La new economic geography – Krugman : cette théorie se fonde sur le relâchement de certaines hypothèses à propos du modèle de l’homo oeconomicus notamment du côté de l’hypothèse de la concurrence pure et parfaite et des rendements croissants.


Cette géographie économique va emprunter des raisonnements, des méthodes de réflexions, des modèles à l’économie pour expliquer des phénomènes géographiques comme par exemple les villes. Ces deux grandes définitions, une définition par la géographie et une définition par l’économie cohabitent.
Three main questions will be asked:
*question of location - spatial economy - Von Thünen, Weber, Christaller : can we model the location of agricultural, industrial and service activities? In theory, based on the rational and fully informed reasoning and behaviour of the homo oeconomicus, we can verify the models of Von Thünen, Weber and Christaller.
*Theories of trade - international economy - Ricardo : economists think a lot about trade, but very often they do not emphasize the spatial dimension of these exchanges. These theories will question the meaning of the exchanges and the spatial structures that will result from these exchanges. With Ricardo, it will result in a specialization.
*The new economic geography - Krugman: this theory is based on the relaxation of certain hypotheses about the homo oeconomicus model, particularly with regard to the hypothesis of pure and perfect competition and increasing returns.


== Définition par l’histoire des sciences ==
This economic geography will borrow reasoning, reflection methods and models from economics to explain geographical phenomena such as cities. These two broad definitions, a definition by geography and a definition by economics coexist.
Le professeur Staszak n’adhère pas à la définition précédente. Le raisonnement a posteriori essai à mettre de l’ordre dans l’histoire des sciences et ce à quoi elle est arrivée, néanmoins, l’histoire des sciences ne résulte pas de projets menés à leur terme. Les entreprises de définitions d’écoles, de courants de discipline, tendent à mettre de l’ordre là où il n’y en a pas. On peut par exemple réfléchir à la différence entre géographie et sociologie en terme logique par une méthode, ou encore une épistémologie. On a l’impression de créer du sens, mais cela est souvent une illusion. Plutôt que d’essayer de définir la géographie économique en essayant de définir un objet ou une méthode, il est plus pertinent de s’intéresser au fait qui fait qu’aujourd’hui il existe un sous-champ de la géographie qui est la géographie économique.


Quand est née la géographie économique ?
== Definition by the history of science ==
Professor Staszak does not agree with the previous definition. The reasoning a posteriori tries to put order in the history of science and what it came to, however, the history of science does not result from projects conducted at their end. School definition companies, disciplinary trends, tend to put order where there is none. One can for example reflect on the difference between geography and sociology in logical terms by a method, or an epistemology. One has the impression of creating meaning, but this is often an illusion. Rather than trying to define economic geography by trying to define an object or a method, it is more relevant to focus on the fact that today there is a subfield of geography which is economic geography.


=== La tradition de la recension, de Colbert à la géographie coloniale et vidalienne : décrire la distribution des richesses ===
When was economic geography born?


On ne trouve pas le terme de « géographie économique » avant la fin du XIXème siècle, mais cela ne veut pas dire qu’on n’en faisait pas. Pour donner une date de naissance à la géographie économique, il est possible de remonter à Louis XIV et Colbert au moment où pour la première fois, un État, l’État français en l’occurrence, s’occupe de la comptabilité des richesses. La question de faire une comptabilité permet de définir les impôts et la guerre. Il y a un moment où les États ont senti le besoin de comptabiliser et de localiser leurs richesses menant à la production de compte, de statistiques et de cartes. On ne cherche pas à expliquer, mais plutôt à décrire. Se met en place une géographie qui tente de décrire, cartographier et comptabiliser les richesses à des fins productives.
=== The tradition of the census, from Colbert to colonial and vidalian geography: describe the distribution of wealth ===


La géographie descriptive est une invention de l’État qui s’est accrue au XIXème siècle avec la colonisation. Une demande est faite aux géographes de produire une information sur les richesses, les potentiels de colonies en termes de matières premières, mais aussi de démographie. Une géographie coloniale produit une information à propos des colonies dans l’idée d’une exploitation. Cette géographie existe toujours aujourd’hui ayant pour but de recenser les richesses, leur distribution spatiale, les facteurs de production à des fins de meilleur développement, de meilleure production, mais aussi d’enrichissement. C’est une géographie qui produit beaucoup d’atlas, de tableaux et de statistiques.
The term "economic geography" was not used until the end of the 19th century, but this does not mean that it was not used. To give a date of birth to economic geography, it is possible to go back to Louis XIV and Colbert when for the first time, a State, the French State in this case, took care of the accounting of wealth. The question of accounting defines taxes and war. There was a time when States felt the need to count and locate their wealth leading to the production of accounts, statistics and maps. We are not trying to explain, but rather to describe. A geography is being developed that attempts to describe, map and account for wealth for productive purposes.


=== La nouvelle géographie et ses emprunts à l’économie spatiale : expliquer l’organisation de l’espace ===
Descriptive geography is an invention of the state that grew in the 19th century with colonization. Geographers are asked to produce information on the wealth and potential of colonies in terms of raw materials, but also demography. A colonial geography produces information about the colonies in the idea of exploitation. This geography still exists today with the aim of identifying wealth, its spatial distribution, factors of production for better development, better production, but also enrichment. It is a geography that produces many atlases, tables and statistics.


Le deuxième courant est plus récent émergeant dans les années 1960 avec l’idée que l’espace économique peut être expliqué. Il y a des lois à chercher comme des lois qui expliquent le marché, les prix ou encore l’échange. Les géographes en utilisant ces lois pourraient peut-être expliquer des phénomènes comme l’organisation de l’espace. Jusqu’aux années 1960, la géographie était très descriptive. Dans les années 1960, l’approche descriptive est décriée comme étant peu scientifique. Il existerait des structures communes parce qu’il y a des lois sur le comportement spatial des êtres humaines. Le but de la géographie économique est d’identifier ces structures universelles de l’espace qui sont liées au comportement économique. Cette géographie n’est plus descriptive, mais n’a juste pour but que de trouver des lois.
=== The new geography and its borrowing from the space economy: explaining the organization of space ===


=== La critique marxiste et le tiers-mondisme : rendre compte des inégalités et du « développement » ===
The second current is more recent emerging in the 1960s with the idea that the economic space can be explained. There are laws to look for like laws that explain the market, the prices or the exchange. Geographers using these laws could perhaps explain phenomena such as the organization of space. Until the 1960s, geography was very descriptive. In the 1960s, the descriptive approach was decried as unscientific. There would be common structures because there are laws on the spatial behaviour of human beings. The purpose of economic geography is to identify those universal structures of space that are related to economic behaviour. This geography is no longer descriptive, but is only intended to find laws.


Dans les années 1970 va se mettre en place un mouvement de contestation contre cette géographie objective. Les géographes d’inspiration marxiste vont dire que la géographie économique doit servir à des fins de libération, de développement et de justice. Il faut voir comment l’organisation de l’espace économique est liée à la lutte des classes, à des structures d’oppression et à des explications fournies par le marxisme. Va naitre une géographie contestatrice qui va montrer comment l’oppression capitaliste passe par des structures spatiales et une explication qui passe par le matérialisme dialectique.
=== Marxist Criticism and Third Worldism: Accounting for Inequalities and "Development ===


=== Le postmodernisme et le tournant culturel ===
In the 1970s, a protest movement was set up against this objective geography. Marxist-inspired geographers will say that economic geography must be used for liberation, development and justice. We must see how the organization of the economic space is linked to class struggle, oppressive structures and explanations provided by Marxism. A contesting geography will emerge that will show how capitalist oppression passes through spatial structures and an explanation that passes through dialectical materialism.


Dans les années 1990, le postmodernisme réfute les critiques marxistes, tiers-mondistes et plus rationalistes comme la théorie de l’homo oeconomicus. Pour les postmodernistes, il y aurait une illusion à vouloir tout expliquer par une seule théorie. La théorie postmoderniste conteste les grands récits. C’est l’idée qu’il y a eu un savoir produit en occident qui a eu une prétention à avoir une validité universelle. Le monde est en fait fragmenté et éclaté entre des sociétés qui sont caractérisées par des discours propres et incommensurables. Pour expliquer comment fonctionne la Grèce antique, on ne peut utiliser la théorie marxiste. Les postmodernistes insistent sur la contextualisation des savoirs. Le tournant postmoderniste est lié au tournant culturel puisqu’il conduit à renvoyer à la spécificité de chacune de ces situations et l’impossibilité de réduire chacune des situations à un modèle unique. Les quatre traditions sont encore vivantes.
=== Postmodernism and the cultural shift ===


= Les enjeux de la géographie économique =
In the 1990s, postmodernism refuted Marxist, Third World and more rationalist critiques such as the theory of homo oeconomicus. For postmodernists, there would be an illusion in wanting to explain everything by a single theory. Postmodernist theory challenges great narratives. It is the idea that there was knowledge produced in the West that claimed to have universal validity. The world is in fact fragmented and fragmented between societies that are characterized by their own and incommensurable discourses. To explain how ancient Greece works, one cannot use Marxist theory. Postmodernists insist on the contextualisation of knowledge. The postmodernist shift is linked to the cultural shift since it leads to refer to the specificity of each of these situations and the impossibility of reducing each situation to a single model. All four traditions are still alive.


== Enjeux scientifiques ==
= The challenges of economic geography =


Les êtres humains et les sociétés ne sont pas mis dans un espace préalable. L’espace est quelque chose que l’on fabrique et que l’on produit. L’espace n’est pas un contenant parce que l’espace est toujours déjà social, c’est une production sociale. Nous vivons dans un espace plein de significations et de sens, hétérogène, polarisé et structuré. Ces caractéristiques sont celles des sociétés qui l’ont produite. Le professeur Staszak refuse l’idée comme quoi l’espace serait quelque chose dans quoi l’économie prendrait place puisque c’est l’économie qui produit l’espace. Ce type de prise de position a conduit à réévaluer l’importance de l’espace dans les sciences sociales. L’espace n’est pas un contenant neutre dans lequel les évènements prendraient place, mais cela participe de la nature des sociétés et de leur activité.
== Scientific stakes ==


Il y a l‘idée que l’espace en tant que tel est :
Human beings and societies are not put in a prior space. Space is something we make and produce. Space is not a container because space is always already social, it is a social production. We live in a space full of meaning and meaning, heterogeneous, polarized and structured. These characteristics are those of the companies that produced it. Professor Staszak refuses the idea that space would be something in which the economy would take place since it is the economy that produces space. This type of stance has led to a reassessment of the importance of space in the social sciences. Space is not a neutral container in which events would take place, but it is part of the nature of societies and their activity.
*un '''enjeu économique''' : c’est quelque chose que l’on peut vendre comme, par exemple, l’immobilier, les transports ou encore le tourisme ;
*un '''produit de l’économie''' : les infrastructures, la spéculation foncière, le zonage des activités. L’économie est un formidable outil pour produire de l’espace ;
*un '''déterminant de l’économie''' : choix des spécialisations, rentes de situation, coût de transport.


== Enjeux de société ==
There is the idea that space as such is:
*an '''economic stake''': it is something that can be sold such as, for example, real estate, transport or tourism ;
*an '''economic product''': infrastructure, land speculation, zoning of activities. The economy is a great tool to produce space;
*a '''determinant of the economy''': choice of specialisations, situation rents, transport costs.


L’actualité de la géographie économique et son renouvellement a aussi répondu à une demande de la société et des questions urgentes qui se posent. Au moins quatre questions ont acquis une importance essentielle depuis les années 1990 :
== Social issues ==
*la '''mondialisation''' : le débat sociétal s’interroge sur la mondialisation comme créatrice ou destructrices d’emplois, génératrice de richesses, les impacts de l’ouverture des marchés, etc. Ce sont des enjeux politiques qui déterminent le choix des sociétés et qui portent sur l’impact de la mondialisation à mesurer qualitativement et quantitativement. La géographie économique est attentive à la variété des phénomènes dans l’espace, d’autre part, la mondialisation est un phénomène géographique de changement d’échelle, d’ouverture de l’espace, de diminution des obstacles et de l’opacité de l’espace. Si l’économique a des réponses à donner sur le plan théorique dans le cadre d’une épistémologie réaliste où on s’occupe moins du monde comme il devrait être que tel qu’il est, les géographes ont été bien placés pour répondre à ce qui fait la spécificité de la mondialisation et sur ses conséquences notamment spatiales. Il y a eu une énorme inquiétude qui s’est mise en place et encore plus forte suite à la crise financière de 2008.
*les '''inégalités de développement''' : c’était une question très importante à l’agenda politique et social des années 1970. À l’époque on parlait de tiers-monde. Dans les années 1950 et 1960, on s’est rendu compte que la décolonisation ne s’est pas traduite par un décollage économique des anciennes colonies. Il y avait de théories comme celle de Rostow qui prévoyait les différentes phases prévisibles qui allaient se faire étape par étape permettant d’acquérir le développement, l’industrie et la croissance, mais cela ne s’est pas produit. Pendant longtemps, la lecture qui a prévalu était la lecture marxiste avec des formes de néocolonialisme qui continuaient à exploiter les pays du Sud et qui expliqueraient leur sous-développement. Ces explications ont perdu leur attrait avec l’effondrement du bloc soviétique et l’abandon progressiste du paradigme marxiste. Cela continu a être une question importante, parce que très menaçante. À partir du moment où on comprend quelles sont les raisons des inégalités de développement, on se donne des leviers pour comprendre où sont les inégalités de développement dans les pays pauvres et riches. À la question de savoir si la mondialisation est un phénomène positif ou négatif, il n’y a pas de réponse. Sur les inégalités de développement, il n’y a pas de réponse non plus, il n’y a pas d’accord général. Dans les années 1970, il y avait encore de nombreux débats alors qu’aujourd'hui on a accepté l’idée que cela existait et qu’il n’y aurait plus besoin de produire d’explication. Cela ne va pas de soi que des inégalités de développement aussi majeures se mettent en place entre les pays.
*les '''logiques spatiales de la production''' : dans le cadre de l’époque fordiste avec la production de masse, la consommation de masse, produits standardisés, les logiques spatiales sont assez simples à saisir notamment avec le modèle de Weber qui permet de comprendre comment une usine va se localiser pour limiter les coûts de transports. Ces logiques spatiales de production ont changé avec les modes de production postfordiste qui se mettent en place dans les années 1980 où les questions logistiques, de stock et de flux tendus deviennent de plus en plus importantes. Il y a eu une nouvelle façon de gérer la production qui s’est mis en place au moment d’une vague de mondialisation avec la question de la localisation de l’usine. A été acquise une sorte de liberté en matière de localisation qui n’existait pas avant. La question de localisation jusqu’aux années 1950 se posait relativement peu parce qu’il y avait peu de choix, les usines ne pouvaient pas se déplacer. Puis cela devient une question, les entreprises vont s’interroger sur la localisation. La dimension logistique et de la carte de la production est devenue essentielle se traduisant par des délocalisations avec des impacts majeurs.
*'''milieu, risques, ressources et développement durable''' : dans les années 1970, avec le club de Rome, se mettent en place des inquiétudes qui ont percolé dans les esprits. La question des ressources naturelles, des risques naturels, de la population et de l’environnement a acquis une nouvelle actualité avec la thématique du développement durable. Ce n’est pas seulement un problème de l’allocation des ressources dans le temps, mais aussi dans l’espace. À partir des années 1990, il y a le sentiment que la géographie économique avait perdu de son prestige se retrouvant au sein de quelques débats de sociétés.


== La géographie économique en plein essor ==
The topicality of economic geography and its renewal has also responded to a demand from society and urgent questions that arise. At least four issues have gained critical importance since the 1990s:
*'''globalisation''': the societal debate questions globalisation as a creator or destroyer of jobs, a generator of wealth, the impacts of the opening up of markets, etc. These are political issues which determine the choice of societies and which concern the impact of globalisation to be measured qualitatively and quantitatively. Economic geography is attentive to the variety of phenomena in space, on the other hand, globalization is a geographical phenomenon of change of scale, opening of space, reduction of obstacles and opacity of space. If economics has answers to give on the theoretical level in the framework of a realistic epistemology where we are less concerned with the world as it should be than as it is, geographers have been well placed to respond to what makes globalization specific and its consequences especially spatial. There has been enormous concern and even greater concern following the 2008 financial crisis.
*'''Inequalities in development''': this was a very important issue on the political and social agenda in the 1970s. At the time we were talking about third world countries. In the 1950s and 1960s, it was realized that decolonization did not result in an economic take-off of the former colonies. There were theories like Rostow's that foresaw the different predictable phases that would take place step by step to acquire development, industry and growth, but this did not happen. For a long time, the reading that prevailed was Marxist reading with forms of neo-colonialism that continued to exploit the countries of the South and that would explain their underdevelopment. These explanations lost their appeal with the collapse of the Soviet bloc and the progressive abandonment of the Marxist paradigm. This continues to be an important issue, because very threatening. Once we understand the reasons for inequalities in development, we give ourselves levers to understand where the inequalities in development are in poor and rich countries. To the question of whether globalisation is a positive or a negative phenomenon, there is no answer. On inequalities in development, there is no answer either, there is no general agreement. In the 1970s, there were still many debates, whereas today we accepted the idea that this existed and that there would no longer be any need to produce an explanation. It is not self-evident that such major inequalities in development are taking place between countries.
*the '''spatial logics of production''': in the Fordist era with mass production, mass consumption, standardized products, spatial logics are quite simple to grasp, particularly with Weber's model that helps understand how a factory will locate itself to limit transport costs. These spatial logics of production have changed with the post-Fordist modes of production that were set up in the 1980s when logistical, stock and just-in-time flow issues became more and more important. There was a new way of managing production that was introduced at the time of a wave of globalization with the question of the location of the plant. A kind of freedom of location was acquired that did not exist before. Until the 1950s, there was relatively little question of location because there were few choices; the factories could not move. Then it becomes a question, companies will ask themselves about localization. The logistics and production map dimension has become essential, resulting in relocations with major impacts.
*'''environment, risks, resources and sustainable development''': in the 1970s, with the Club of Rome, concerns arose that percolated into people's minds. The issue of natural resources, natural risks, population and the environment has acquired a new topicality with the theme of sustainable development. This is not only a problem of resource allocation in time, but also in space. From the 1990s onwards, there was a feeling that economic geography had lost its prestige in some societal debates.


La sphère de l’économique s’est élargie. Tant est que la géographie de l’économie porte sur l’économie, depuis une vingtaine d’années son domaine d’application a connu une expansion importante. Il y avait des domaines qui ne relevaient pas de l’économique et qui y sont entrés. Ces logiques sont celles de la réussite de l’économie de marché et de son extension. Des secteurs qui ne faisaient pas de l’économie de marché comme l’éducation, la culture ou la santé sont devenus des enjeux économiques. Les raisons pour lesquels on a essayé de faire entrer ans l’économie de marché des secteurs qui n’y était pas se traduit par une meilleure allocation des ressources. Les années 1980 furent les années où l’État a abandonné des secteurs de l’économie qu’il avait à charge au secteur privé. Le champ de l’économique s’étant élargi, le champ de la géographie économique s’est étendu également.
== Economic geography in full expansion ==


On a cru longtemps que l’espace perdait en importance avec la diminution des coûts de transports et des modes de télécommunications de plus en plus performants. Jamais autant qu’aujourd’hui il n’a été facile de transformer des biens matériels et immatériels. Grâce à la Première, Deuxième et Troisième révolution des transports, on a l’impression que l’être humain s’est dégagé de la problématique de la distance. Cela aurait voulu donc dire la fin de la géographie et de la géographie économique, car l’espace ne compterait plus et la question de l’organisation de l’espace ne se poserait plus.
The economic sphere has expanded. As much as the geography of the economy is about the economy, over the past twenty years its field of application has expanded significantly. There were areas that were not economic, and they got into it. These logics are those of the success of the market economy and its extension. Sectors that were not market economies such as education, culture or health have become economic issues. The reasons for trying to bring the market economy into sectors that were not there are reflected in a better allocation of resources. The 1980s were the years when the state abandoned sectors of the economy it had in charge of the private sector. As the field of economics has expanded, the field of economic geography has also expanded.


On communique aussi facilement avec son voisin qu’avec un collègue qui habite à l’autre bout de la planète est un postulat qui est faux. Les modes de communications sont différents et adaptatifs. Internet, loin de faire disparaître les logiques spatiales, les fait apparaître. On peut argumenter l’idée que le transport de l’information est plus facile aujourd’hui que dans le passé, mais il y a eu une telle augmentation dans la quantité de l’information transportée et dans la complexité de l’information transportée que c’est aujourd’hui un plus grand problème qu’hier. L’amélioration des conditions de transport de l’information ne compense pas l’augmentation colossale de nos besoins en informations et en informations complexes.
For a long time it was believed that space was losing importance as transport costs and increasingly efficient telecommunications modes decreased. Never has it been so easy to transform tangible and intangible goods as it is today. Thanks to the First, Second and Third Transport Revolutions, we have the impression that the human being has freed himself from the problem of distance. This would therefore have meant the end of geography and economic geography, because space would no longer count and the question of the organization of space would no longer arise.


Dans les années 1970, on pensait que les universités étaient terminées. Il y avait l’idée que dans l’avenir on arriverait à faire des cours à distance. La coprésence matérielle représente un coût énorme. La complexité de l’information ne résume pas à un discours. L’information ne passe pas uniquement par la parole, mais par d’autres aspects. L’incapacité à transporter facilement de l’information complexe explique certains modes de communications plus classiques qui nécessitent de se déplacer dans l’espace. La délocalisation nécessite du contrôle.
One communicates as easily with one's neighbour as with a colleague who lives on the other side of the world is a false assumption. Communication modes are different and adaptive. Far from making spatial logic disappear, the Internet makes it appear. The idea that the transport of information is easier today than in the past can be argued, but there has been such an increase in the quantity of information transported and in the complexity of the information transported that today it is a greater problem than in the past. The improvement in information transport conditions does not compensate for the colossal increase in our needs for information and complex information.


== La géographie économique en plein renouveau ==
In the 1970s, universities were thought to be over. There was the idea that in the future we would be able to take courses at a distance. Material co-presence is a huge cost. The complexity of information is not just a speech. Information does not only come through words, but through other aspects. The inability to easily transport complex information explains some of the more traditional modes of communication that require moving through space. Offshoring requires control.


La géographie économique a connu un essor lié à ces nouveaux enjeux et ces nouvelles demandes, mais cela est aussi lié à des mutations épistémologiques et théoriques qui sont celles d’un tournant culturel de la géographie économique qui fut pris dans les années 1990. Pendant longtemps, le monde de l’économie a été considéré comme un monde autonome qui avait ses propres logiques comme des logiques de la rationalité avec le modèle de Christaller par exemple qui ramenait l’espace à quelques explications. Ce consensus s’est effrité dans les années 1980 et ont émergé des approches culturelles dans les années 1990.
== Economic geography in full revival ==


L’irruption de la culture dans l’économie est liée au fait qu’on vend de moins en moins de biens matériels et de plus en plus de biens symboliques. Autrement dit, il y a de plus en plus de symboles dans les biens que l’on vend et les biens matériels. On fabrique de moins en moins d’objets et de plus en plus d’idée et que dans les objets qu’on fabrique, la composante utilitaire est de moins en moins importante que la composante symbolique qui l’est de plus en plus. La culture est devenue sans doute le premier bien économique des pays riches. Il y a un phénomène de tertiarisation de l’industrie, tandis que l’industrie se tourner vers de plus en plus de la manipulation de symbole. Cela ne veut pas nécessairement dire qu’il faut analyser ces industries culturelles d’une nouvelle façon. Lorsqu’on parle d’un tournant culturel, ce sont les économistes eux-mêmes avec trois grandes tendances :
Economic geography has experienced a boom linked to these new challenges and these new demands, but this is also linked to epistemological and theoretical changes that are those of a cultural turning point in economic geography that was taken in the 1990s. For a long time, the world of economics was considered as an autonomous world which had its own logics as logics of rationality with Christaller's model for example which reduced space to a few explanations. This consensus crumbled in the 1980s and emerged from cultural approaches in the 1990s.
*une '''économie « encastrée »''' (Polanyi [1943], Granovetter [1985] et la new economic sociology) (dans le social, dans l’espace) : c’est l’idée de marquer une rupture vis-à-vis des modes de pensées des économistes qui considéraient le monde de l’économie comme un monde à part qu’on pouvait considérer, modéliser et théoriser en faisant abstraction du contexte dans lequel il se trouvait. C’était l’autonomisation de l’économique. Il était possible de comprendre le fonctionnement d’une société en la coupant de son fonctionnement politique ou de son fonctionnement spatial, mais également de son inscription dans l’espace. Polania et Granovetter ont montré que l’économie est très profondément encastrée dans le social et le politique, il n’y a pas à distinguer le tissu social, politique et économique. Lorsqu’on regarde le fonctionnement réel de l’économique et du sociale, l’économie est profondément encastrée dans l’économique et le social. Au fond, on ne pouvait pas le comprendre parce qu’on travaillait sur une fiction dégagée de son caractère encastré dans le social.
*les '''économistes hétérodoxes''' (post-autistic economics) : il y a eu le développement des économistes hétérodoxes qui acceptent et qui ont développé d‘autres façons de faire de l’économie. Ces économistes hétérodoxes ont pris en compte le social, le politique avec l’école des conventions, l’économie institutionnelle, l’idée du marché comme fiction notamment. Cela a amené au développent de nouveaux courants économiques pris en compte par les géographes qui ont essayé de comprendre dans quelle mesure on peut le théoriser dans le cadre de la compréhension de l’espace.
*'''variété des cultures de production et de consommation, des formes de capitalisme''' (épistémologie « réaliste ») : pour comprendre les modes de consommation et de production, il faut regarder la réalité dans l’espace de la variété des comportements.


On distingue essentiellement trois directions principales :
The irruption of culture in the economy is linked to the fact that fewer and fewer material goods are being sold and more and more symbolic goods are being sold. In other words, there are more and more symbols in the goods that are sold and the material goods. We make fewer and fewer objects and more and more ideas and that in the objects we make, the utilitarian component is less and less important than the symbolic component which is more and more important. Culture has undoubtedly become the first economic good of the rich countries. There is a phenomenon of tertiarization of industry, while industry is turning more and more to symbol manipulation. This does not necessarily mean that these cultural industries must be analyzed in a new way. When we speak of a cultural turning point, it is the economists themselves with three major trends:
*l’'''espace est fondamentalement impliqué dans les processus économiques''' (école de Los Angeles, école française de la proximité) : les deux écoles sont parties d’une même interrogation qui est celle qu’alors que le transport n’a jamais été aussi bon marché, alors qu’on produit des biens de plus en plus matériels,l’économie n’a jamais été aussi concentrée dans l’espace avec l’émergence de districts industriels. L’exemple paradigmatique est la Silicon valley au sud de San Francisco où se trouve l’université de Sanford. Ce district est devenu l’hypercentre mondial de la production et de la recherche en la matière soulevant la question de savoir pourquoi ils se sont tous mis au même endroit. L’une des réponses et que ce sont des informations tellement sensibles et complexes qu’il faut se voir. Les districts industriels sont des endroits où va se concentrer un type de production avec des structures de production assez particulières. On utilise aussi le terme de district de production spécialisé (SPL). Dans les politiques d’aménagent du territoire, on essaie de faire émerger des districts industriels. C’est ce mystère qui a amené à l’école de la proximité de Los Angeles et française à se développer. C’est une direction dans la recherche qui est d’autant plus importante qu’elle a un impact direct sur les politiques de développement.
*a "built-in" economy (Polanyi[1943], Granovetter[1985] and the new economic sociology) (in the social, in space)  it is the idea of marking a break with the modes of thought of economists who considered the world of economics as a world apart that one could consider, model and theorize while making abstraction of the context in which it was found. It was economic empowerment. It was possible to understand the functioning of a society by cutting it off from its political functioning or from its spatial functioning, but also from its place in space. Polania and Granovetter have shown that the economy is very deeply embedded in the social and political, there is no need to distinguish the social, political and economic fabric. When we look at the real functioning of the economic and the social, the economy is deeply embedded in the economic and the social. Basically, we couldn't understand it because we were working on a fiction that was free from its social embedded character.
*les '''composantes non-économiques de l’économie''' (modes de régulation, institutions, cultures d’entreprise, cultures de consommation, etc.) : des géographes se sont mis à travailler sur des objets que l’on considérait comme des objets économiques comme le shopping mall que l’on ne peut comprendre si on le réduit à un objet économique. Le shopping mall est devenu une forme de lieu de sociabilité.
*heterodox economists (post-autistic economics): there has been the development of heterodox economists who accept and have developed other ways of doing business. These heterodox economists have taken into account the social, the political with the school of conventions, institutional economics, the idea of the market as fiction in particular. This has led to the development of new economic currents taken into account by geographers who have tried to understand to what extent it can be theorized in the framework of understanding space.
*la '''nouvelle économie géographique''' : Krugman propose une nouvelle théorie des échanges internationaux et des inégalités. Contrairement aux deux précédents, Krugman est dans le modèle de l‘économie libérale. Dans les grandes hypothèses de l’économie libérale, il va laisser tomber l’hypothèse de la concurrence pure et parfaite en mettant l’accent sur les rendements croissants qui permet de mieux comprendre les inégalités de développement.
*variety of production and consumption cultures, forms of capitalism ("realistic" epistemology): to understand consumption and production patterns, we must look at reality in the space of the variety of behaviours.


= Exemples =
There are essentially three main directions:
*'''Space is fundamentally involved in economic processes''' (Los Angeles school, French school of proximity): the two schools started from the same question which is that whereas transport has never been so cheap, whereas goods are produced more and more material, the economy has never been so concentrated in space with the emergence of industrial districts. The paradigmatic example is the Silicon valley south of San Francisco where Sanford University is located. This district has become the world's hypercentre for production and research in the field, raising the question of why they have all put themselves in the same place. One of the answers is that this information is so sensitive and complex that we need to see each other. Industrial districts are places where a type of production will be concentrated with quite particular production structures. The term Specialized Production District (SPL) is also used. In spatial planning policies, we try to bring out industrial districts. It was this mystery that led to the school's proximity to Los Angeles and French to develop. It is a direction in research that is all the more important because it has a direct impact on development policies.
*the '''non-economic components of the economy''' (modes of regulation, institutions, corporate cultures, consumer cultures, etc.): geographers began to work on objects that were considered as economic objects such as the shopping mall that cannot be understood if it is reduced to an economic object. The shopping mall has become a form of place of sociability.
*the '''new geographical economy''': Krugman proposes a new theory of international trade and inequality. Unlike the previous two, Krugman is in the liberal economy model. In the major assumptions of the liberal economy, he will drop the hypothesis of pure and perfect competition by emphasizing increasing returns that allows a better understanding of inequalities in development.
 
= Examples =


== San Paolo ==
== San Paolo ==
[[Fichier:Geoeco exemple sao paolo plateforme 1.png|vignette]]
[[Fichier:Geoeco exemple sao paolo plateforme 1.png|vignette]]


Sur cet immeuble, une plateforme a été installée. San Paolo est une agglomération énorme. Cet immeuble se trouve dans un centre historique. La présence d’un café internet atteste probablement que les gens n’ont pas internet chez eux. Le café internet manifeste la potentialité d’être en contact avec le monde entier pour un coût quasiment nul, mais en même temps il ne l’est pas.
A platform has been installed on this building. San Paolo is a huge agglomeration. This building is located in a historical centre. The presence of an internet café probably attests that people do not have internet at home. The internet café shows the potential to be in contact with the whole world for almost no cost, but at the same time it is not.
 
Avec ce paysage urbain, il y a comme trois espaces économiques qui cohabitent :
*l’espace de la rue ;
*l’espace de la mondialisation ;
*l’espace manifesté par les tours de bureaux et l’héliport.


Il y a des incompatibilités entre ces trois types d’espaces. Des choses ne peuvent fonctionner en même temps. Toutes ces échelles fonctionnent en même temps.
With this urban landscape, there are like three economic spaces that cohabit:
* the space of the street;
* the space of globalization;
* the space manifested by the office towers and the heliport.
There are incompatibilities between these three types of spaces. Things can't work at the same time. All these scales work at the same time.


== Les Indes occidentales – Théodore de Bry ==
== The West Indies – Théodore de Bry ==
[[Fichier:Geoeco exemple théodore de bry 1.jpg|vignette]]
[[Fichier:Geoeco exemple théodore de bry 1.jpg|vignette]]


Cette gravure de Théodore de Bry montre l’arrivée de Christophe Colomb dans les Indes occidentales. La gravure date de 1590 environ cent années après l’arrivée de Christophe Colomb imaginant cette rencontre. Apparaissent les trois caravelles de Christophe Colomb, les hommes qui débarquent, l’urgence est de poser une croix puisqu’il y a la question de l’évangélisation, et puis il y a le pouvoir, l’armée et le drapeau. Les indigènes sont nus parce que ce sont des sauvages et il fait chaud, d’autres s’enfuient. Les indigènes offrent des présents.
This engraving of Theodore de Bry shows the arrival of Christopher Columbus in the West Indies. The engraving dates from 1590 about a hundred years after the arrival of Christopher Columbus imagining this encounter. The three caravels of Christopher Columbus appear, the men who land, the urgency is to place a cross since there is the question of evangelization, and then there is power, the army and the flag. The natives are naked because they are savages and it is hot, others flee. The natives give presents.


A lieu un échange économique. Il y a deux attitudes chez les sauvages avec ceux qui se sauvent et ceux qui offrent des présents. Il y a un échange de richesses qui ne passe pas par le marché. Il y a un échange unilatéral qui pose la question de la logique de cet échange. Pourquoi offre-t-il a Colomb ? Ils font de Christophe Colomb leur débiteur en échange de la vie. L’idée est qu’on essaie d’amadouer des agresseurs potentiels en leur offrant quelque chose. Christophe Colomb est parti pour court-circuiter la route de la soie et d’arriver directement en Chine par l’ouest. Le but du voyage était purement économique pour alimenter les caisses hispaniques en se déroutant de la route de la soie. Il est possible de faire une analyse en termes de géographie économique.
There is an economic exchange. There are two attitudes among savages with those who run away and those who offer gifts. There is an exchange of wealth that does not pass through the market. There is a unilateral exchange that raises the question of the logic of this exchange. Why is he offering Columbus? They make Christopher Columbus their debtor in exchange for life. The idea is that we try to coax potential attackers by offering them something. Christopher Columbus left to short-circuit the Silk Road and arrive directly in China from the west. The purpose of the trip was purely economic to feed the Hispanic coffers by diverting from the Silk Road. It is possible to make an analysis in terms of economic geography.


== Initiation à la géographie régionale – Paul Claval ==
== Introduction to regional geography – Paul Claval ==
[[Fichier:Geoeco exemple ouvrage paul claval 1.jpg|vignette]]
[[Fichier:Geoeco exemple ouvrage paul claval 1.jpg|vignette]]


Paul Claval était l’un des penseurs importants de la géographie économique. On a l’impression qu’il y a deux types d’organisation de l’espace très différents. En bas de l’espace, on sent une présence humaine et une artificialisation très marquée. Le quadrige très marqué n’est pas la nature, cela est une organisation de l’espace faite par les sociétés humaines. Au nord on ne retrouve pas ce quadrillage, de plus, cela n’est pas la même couleur. En bas, ce sont des champs cultivés et en haut ce sont des forêts.
Paul Claval was one of the important thinkers of economic geography. We have the impression that there are two very different types of organization of space. At the bottom of space, we feel a human presence and a very marked artificialisation. The very marked quadrige is not nature, it is an organization of space made by human societies. In the north we do not find this grid, moreover, it is not the same color. At the bottom they are cultivated fields and at the top they are forests.


On a l’impression que sont pris en photographie deux espaces cultivés donnant l’impression de deux photos d’autant plus que la limite entre les deux, il y a deux espaces rectilignes. Néanmoins, ce n’est qu’une photo qui relate un même espace où il y a simplement une opposition à la fois très forte entre deux types de productions économiques différentes.
One has the impression that two cultivated spaces are taken in photography giving the impression of two photos, all the more so as the boundary between the two, there are two rectilinear spaces. Nevertheless, it is only a photo that relates the same space where there is simply a very strong opposition between two different types of economic production.


L’une des premières explications peut être celle du climat. Le passage d’un climat à l’autre se fait graduellement, il n’y a aucune raison pour que cela corresponde à une telle limite. Cette image représente la frontière entre les États-Unis et le Canada. L’explication est dans le système politique. On est dans un endroit où normalement il n’y a aucune raison de produire des céréales parce que le coût de la main-d’œuvre, la nature des sols est tel que cela n’est pas rentable. Le Canada a arrêté de produire du blé au contraire des États-Unis qui continuent la céréaliculture à perte. Leur intérêt serait d’arrêter de produire du blé et d’en importer. La raison d’une telle production est parce que cela est subventionné. L’État va reverser la différente de prix.
One of the first explanations may be the climate. The transition from one climate to the other is gradual, there is no reason why it should correspond to such a limit. This image represents the border between the United States and Canada. The explanation is in the political system. We are in a place where there is normally no reason to produce grain because the cost of labour and the nature of the soil is such that it is not profitable. Canada has stopped producing wheat, unlike the United States, which continues to produce grain at a loss. Their interest would be to stop producing wheat and import it. The reason for such production is because it is subsidized. The state will pay the different price.


La raison n’est pas liée à un état d’esprit, la nature de sol ou au froid, au nord ce n’est que de la forêt parce que le blé n’est pas subventionné. Plusieurs raisons expliquent pourquoi un pays ne peut pas renoncer à son agriculture parce qu’un pays doit être autonome sur le plan alimentaire, parce que le blé est une arme, parce que l’espace rural est un enjeu du point de vue identitaire. Il fut un temps où la géographie était les contraintes du milieu naturel. La géographie est présente dans cette ligne qui oppose deux espaces structurés différents. Il y a deux systèmes légaux et politiques différents qui prennent place de façon opposée dans la mondialisation. Les États-Unis du fait de leur puissance arrivent à imposer le libre-échange sans l’appliquer eux-mêmes au contraire du Canada. Le facteur premier qui expliquer cette opposition est un facteur strictement économique qui est les subventions versées.
The reason is not related to a state of mind, soil nature or cold, to the north, it is only forest because wheat is not subsidized. There are several reasons why a country cannot give up its agriculture because a country must be food self-sufficient, because wheat is a weapon, because rural areas are an issue from an identity point of view. There was a time when geography was the constraints of the natural environment. Geography is present in this line which opposes two different structured spaces. There are two different legal and political systems that take place in opposite ways in globalization. Because of its power, the United States is able to impose free trade without applying it itself, unlike Canada. The primary factor explaining this opposition is a strictly economic factor, which is the subsidies paid.


==  Le marché à la Martinique ==
==  The market in Martinique ==
[[Fichier:Geoeco exemple marché martinique 1.png|vignette]]
[[Fichier:Geoeco exemple marché martinique 1.png|vignette]]


C’est un marché touristique. On est dans une ancienne structure de marché qui est une structure en métal avec des poteaux ondulés. C’est une structure fin XIXème siècle et début XXème siècle qui était à l’origine certainement un marché local mise en place par l’administration française. La diffusion de l’économie de marché par l’administration française se traduisait par la mise en place de marché pour centraliser les échanges à un endroit avec une périodicité et un contrôle de poids et de mesures.
It's a tourist market. We are in an old market structure that is a metal structure with corrugated posts. It is a late 19th and early 20th century structure which was certainly originally a local market set up by the French administration. The spread of the market economy by the French administration resulted in the establishment of a market to centralize trade at one place with periodicity and control of weight and measures.


Si on regarde ces produits, on s’aperçoit que les différents stands présentent des produits comparables, mais aussi organisés de la même façon. On voit que toutes ces boutiques ont l’air de vendre exactement la même chose. Quelque chose ne semble pas rationnel qui d’une part est vendre du « made in china » dans un marché martiniquais, d’autre part, la structure commerciale de ces commerces qui vendent tous la même chose présentée de la même façon.
If we look at these products, we notice that the different stands present comparable products, but also organized in the same way. You can see that all these shops seem to sell exactly the same thing. Something does not seem rational which on the one hand is selling "made in china" in a Martinican market, on the other hand, the commercial structure of these businesses which all sell the same thing presented in the same way.


La raison pour laquelle l’arrangement est tel n’est sans doute pas parce que chacune de ces actrices économiques est égoïstes, pleinement rationnelle, informée et cherche à maximiser son utilité indépendamment de ses voisines. Peut être que ces actrices ne sont pas rationnelles, informées, peut être qu’elles cherchent autre chose que leur utilité, peut être qu’elles ne décident pas toutes seules. Il faut injecter quelque chose qui n’est pas le modèle de l’homo oeconomicus dans ce lieu de vente qui est le marché.
The reason why the arrangement is such is probably not because each of these economic actors is selfish, fully rational, informed and seeks to maximize its utility independently of its neighbours. Maybe these actresses are not rational, informed, maybe they seek something other than their utility, maybe they don't decide alone. We have to inject something that is not the homo oeconomicus model into this place of sale, which is the market.


Une première explication est que nous sommes à un stade précoce du développement économique où les modèles sont peu nombreux, il n’y a pas encore eu le moment d’une diversification où chacun met en place un modèle différent. Une autre explication est que les vendeuses ne sont pas en concurrence réglant le conflit entre ces deux personnes. Le partage de la clientèle ne dépend pas des marchands, la clientèle va être distribuée de façon aléatoire par le choix des clients. La concurrence est annulée permettant d’éviter des conflits, mais aussi de maintenir les prix à un certain niveau. Un troisième type d’explication serait de se dire que ces magasins sont tenus par des propriétaires et que les vendeuses sont employées, le système économique est tel que les vendeuses n’ont pas d’intéressement à la vente et elles ne sont pas motivés pour faire du bénéfice.
A first explanation is that we are at an early stage of economic development where there are few models, there has not yet been a time for diversification where everyone sets up a different model. Another explanation is that the vendors are not competing to resolve the conflict between these two people. The sharing of the clientele does not depend on the merchants, the clientele will be distributed randomly by the choice of the clients. Competition is cancelled in order to avoid conflicts, but also to maintain prices at a certain level. A third type of explanation would be to say that these stores are owner-owned and the saleswomen are employed, the economic system is such that the saleswomen have no incentive to sell and they are not motivated to make a profit.


En termes de géographie économique, deux éléments sont intéressants : le passage d’un marché à un autre et l’explication des stands qui sont tous exactement les mêmes.
In terms of economic geography, two elements are interesting: the transition from one market to another and the explanation of the stands which are all exactly the same.


= Annexes =
= Annexes =


= References =
= References =
<references/>
<references />


[[Category:Jean-François Staszak]]
[[Category:Jean-François Staszak]]

Version actuelle datée du 5 janvier 2020 à 13:59


The history of trade is part of a long history of globalization from the 15th century. We are not just going to talk about the market economy, a part of the economy is not regulated by the market. Economists and sometimes economic geography are obsessed with the market. In our daily lives, a huge part of production, consumption and economic exchange is regulated other than by the market. Much emphasis will be placed on the forms of regulation of the economy that are not those of the market economy, i.e. donation for donation and redistribution. The economy is embedded in social and cultural and often economic behaviours are explained by factors that are other than economic, the explanation may be outside the economy.

A certain number of theories will be tackled such as the theory of the opening up of economic circuits, the geography of comparative advantages and increasing returns, spatial inequalities in development or the environmental question. Economic geography is sometimes reduced to a description of the world, we will develop a cultural approach that is a current of economic geography for fifteen years.

What is economic geography?[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

Definition by disciplines[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

There are several ways to define economic geography. One way is to place economic geography at the crossroads of two disciplines with geography on one side and economics on the other. Nevertheless, there are canonical definitions:

  • Geography is a science that is interested in the organization of space to the special dimension of societies. It is a social science that deals with space and its organization.
  • Economics is a science that deals with the production, circulation and consumption of rare goods.

How can we cross economic geography, production and consumption of rare goods as well as the question of the organization of space?

Definition by object[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

Geography has an object, it is a geography of economics. There is economics, production, consumption, the exchange of rare goods, and we are going to make a geography of it by looking at the spatial dimension of economics, how the spatial dimension of the economy is organized, that is, where production takes place, where consumption takes place, through which the exchange of rare goods takes place. It means locating economics, production, consumption and trade.

When it comes to economic geography, there are very varied explanations:

  • orthodox economics ;
  • economic heterodox: neo-Marxism, school of conventions ;
  • non-economic: anthropology, economic sociology ;
  • cultural turning point in economic geography: paying attention to cultural elements.

Economic geography is a geography of the economic world.

Definition by approach[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

Economic geography would be geography through economics, that is, adopting economic reasoning, explaining geographical facts using economic reasoning. It is making an economic interpretation of geography by using economic theories to explain geographical facts. Will be borrowed from the economic model of homo oeconomicus and try to see what are the laws of its spatial behavior.

Homo oeconomicus behaves in terms of supply and demand, but also in space. This behaviour can be modelled and quantified so that its consequences can be studied by aggregating individual behaviours. In a homogeneous space populated by homo oeconomicus who all follow the laws of rationality, fully informed, selfish tending to maximize their profit, their spatial choices, where they live, produce, consume will follow certain laws and that these laws will emerge spatial structures. Economic geography, by studying homo oeconomicus, will see how the spatial behaviours of human beings result from large forms of spatial organizations. They are experiments of the mind, namely economic models, whose spatial components we try to see.

Three main questions will be asked:

  • question of location - spatial economy - Von Thünen, Weber, Christaller : can we model the location of agricultural, industrial and service activities? In theory, based on the rational and fully informed reasoning and behaviour of the homo oeconomicus, we can verify the models of Von Thünen, Weber and Christaller.
  • Theories of trade - international economy - Ricardo : economists think a lot about trade, but very often they do not emphasize the spatial dimension of these exchanges. These theories will question the meaning of the exchanges and the spatial structures that will result from these exchanges. With Ricardo, it will result in a specialization.
  • The new economic geography - Krugman: this theory is based on the relaxation of certain hypotheses about the homo oeconomicus model, particularly with regard to the hypothesis of pure and perfect competition and increasing returns.

This economic geography will borrow reasoning, reflection methods and models from economics to explain geographical phenomena such as cities. These two broad definitions, a definition by geography and a definition by economics coexist.

Definition by the history of science[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

Professor Staszak does not agree with the previous definition. The reasoning a posteriori tries to put order in the history of science and what it came to, however, the history of science does not result from projects conducted at their end. School definition companies, disciplinary trends, tend to put order where there is none. One can for example reflect on the difference between geography and sociology in logical terms by a method, or an epistemology. One has the impression of creating meaning, but this is often an illusion. Rather than trying to define economic geography by trying to define an object or a method, it is more relevant to focus on the fact that today there is a subfield of geography which is economic geography.

When was economic geography born?

The tradition of the census, from Colbert to colonial and vidalian geography: describe the distribution of wealth[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

The term "economic geography" was not used until the end of the 19th century, but this does not mean that it was not used. To give a date of birth to economic geography, it is possible to go back to Louis XIV and Colbert when for the first time, a State, the French State in this case, took care of the accounting of wealth. The question of accounting defines taxes and war. There was a time when States felt the need to count and locate their wealth leading to the production of accounts, statistics and maps. We are not trying to explain, but rather to describe. A geography is being developed that attempts to describe, map and account for wealth for productive purposes.

Descriptive geography is an invention of the state that grew in the 19th century with colonization. Geographers are asked to produce information on the wealth and potential of colonies in terms of raw materials, but also demography. A colonial geography produces information about the colonies in the idea of exploitation. This geography still exists today with the aim of identifying wealth, its spatial distribution, factors of production for better development, better production, but also enrichment. It is a geography that produces many atlases, tables and statistics.

The new geography and its borrowing from the space economy: explaining the organization of space[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

The second current is more recent emerging in the 1960s with the idea that the economic space can be explained. There are laws to look for like laws that explain the market, the prices or the exchange. Geographers using these laws could perhaps explain phenomena such as the organization of space. Until the 1960s, geography was very descriptive. In the 1960s, the descriptive approach was decried as unscientific. There would be common structures because there are laws on the spatial behaviour of human beings. The purpose of economic geography is to identify those universal structures of space that are related to economic behaviour. This geography is no longer descriptive, but is only intended to find laws.

Marxist Criticism and Third Worldism: Accounting for Inequalities and "Development[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

In the 1970s, a protest movement was set up against this objective geography. Marxist-inspired geographers will say that economic geography must be used for liberation, development and justice. We must see how the organization of the economic space is linked to class struggle, oppressive structures and explanations provided by Marxism. A contesting geography will emerge that will show how capitalist oppression passes through spatial structures and an explanation that passes through dialectical materialism.

Postmodernism and the cultural shift[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

In the 1990s, postmodernism refuted Marxist, Third World and more rationalist critiques such as the theory of homo oeconomicus. For postmodernists, there would be an illusion in wanting to explain everything by a single theory. Postmodernist theory challenges great narratives. It is the idea that there was knowledge produced in the West that claimed to have universal validity. The world is in fact fragmented and fragmented between societies that are characterized by their own and incommensurable discourses. To explain how ancient Greece works, one cannot use Marxist theory. Postmodernists insist on the contextualisation of knowledge. The postmodernist shift is linked to the cultural shift since it leads to refer to the specificity of each of these situations and the impossibility of reducing each situation to a single model. All four traditions are still alive.

The challenges of economic geography[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

Scientific stakes[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

Human beings and societies are not put in a prior space. Space is something we make and produce. Space is not a container because space is always already social, it is a social production. We live in a space full of meaning and meaning, heterogeneous, polarized and structured. These characteristics are those of the companies that produced it. Professor Staszak refuses the idea that space would be something in which the economy would take place since it is the economy that produces space. This type of stance has led to a reassessment of the importance of space in the social sciences. Space is not a neutral container in which events would take place, but it is part of the nature of societies and their activity.

There is the idea that space as such is:

  • an economic stake: it is something that can be sold such as, for example, real estate, transport or tourism ;
  • an economic product: infrastructure, land speculation, zoning of activities. The economy is a great tool to produce space;
  • a determinant of the economy: choice of specialisations, situation rents, transport costs.

Social issues[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

The topicality of economic geography and its renewal has also responded to a demand from society and urgent questions that arise. At least four issues have gained critical importance since the 1990s:

  • globalisation: the societal debate questions globalisation as a creator or destroyer of jobs, a generator of wealth, the impacts of the opening up of markets, etc. These are political issues which determine the choice of societies and which concern the impact of globalisation to be measured qualitatively and quantitatively. Economic geography is attentive to the variety of phenomena in space, on the other hand, globalization is a geographical phenomenon of change of scale, opening of space, reduction of obstacles and opacity of space. If economics has answers to give on the theoretical level in the framework of a realistic epistemology where we are less concerned with the world as it should be than as it is, geographers have been well placed to respond to what makes globalization specific and its consequences especially spatial. There has been enormous concern and even greater concern following the 2008 financial crisis.
  • Inequalities in development: this was a very important issue on the political and social agenda in the 1970s. At the time we were talking about third world countries. In the 1950s and 1960s, it was realized that decolonization did not result in an economic take-off of the former colonies. There were theories like Rostow's that foresaw the different predictable phases that would take place step by step to acquire development, industry and growth, but this did not happen. For a long time, the reading that prevailed was Marxist reading with forms of neo-colonialism that continued to exploit the countries of the South and that would explain their underdevelopment. These explanations lost their appeal with the collapse of the Soviet bloc and the progressive abandonment of the Marxist paradigm. This continues to be an important issue, because very threatening. Once we understand the reasons for inequalities in development, we give ourselves levers to understand where the inequalities in development are in poor and rich countries. To the question of whether globalisation is a positive or a negative phenomenon, there is no answer. On inequalities in development, there is no answer either, there is no general agreement. In the 1970s, there were still many debates, whereas today we accepted the idea that this existed and that there would no longer be any need to produce an explanation. It is not self-evident that such major inequalities in development are taking place between countries.
  • the spatial logics of production: in the Fordist era with mass production, mass consumption, standardized products, spatial logics are quite simple to grasp, particularly with Weber's model that helps understand how a factory will locate itself to limit transport costs. These spatial logics of production have changed with the post-Fordist modes of production that were set up in the 1980s when logistical, stock and just-in-time flow issues became more and more important. There was a new way of managing production that was introduced at the time of a wave of globalization with the question of the location of the plant. A kind of freedom of location was acquired that did not exist before. Until the 1950s, there was relatively little question of location because there were few choices; the factories could not move. Then it becomes a question, companies will ask themselves about localization. The logistics and production map dimension has become essential, resulting in relocations with major impacts.
  • environment, risks, resources and sustainable development: in the 1970s, with the Club of Rome, concerns arose that percolated into people's minds. The issue of natural resources, natural risks, population and the environment has acquired a new topicality with the theme of sustainable development. This is not only a problem of resource allocation in time, but also in space. From the 1990s onwards, there was a feeling that economic geography had lost its prestige in some societal debates.

Economic geography in full expansion[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

The economic sphere has expanded. As much as the geography of the economy is about the economy, over the past twenty years its field of application has expanded significantly. There were areas that were not economic, and they got into it. These logics are those of the success of the market economy and its extension. Sectors that were not market economies such as education, culture or health have become economic issues. The reasons for trying to bring the market economy into sectors that were not there are reflected in a better allocation of resources. The 1980s were the years when the state abandoned sectors of the economy it had in charge of the private sector. As the field of economics has expanded, the field of economic geography has also expanded.

For a long time it was believed that space was losing importance as transport costs and increasingly efficient telecommunications modes decreased. Never has it been so easy to transform tangible and intangible goods as it is today. Thanks to the First, Second and Third Transport Revolutions, we have the impression that the human being has freed himself from the problem of distance. This would therefore have meant the end of geography and economic geography, because space would no longer count and the question of the organization of space would no longer arise.

One communicates as easily with one's neighbour as with a colleague who lives on the other side of the world is a false assumption. Communication modes are different and adaptive. Far from making spatial logic disappear, the Internet makes it appear. The idea that the transport of information is easier today than in the past can be argued, but there has been such an increase in the quantity of information transported and in the complexity of the information transported that today it is a greater problem than in the past. The improvement in information transport conditions does not compensate for the colossal increase in our needs for information and complex information.

In the 1970s, universities were thought to be over. There was the idea that in the future we would be able to take courses at a distance. Material co-presence is a huge cost. The complexity of information is not just a speech. Information does not only come through words, but through other aspects. The inability to easily transport complex information explains some of the more traditional modes of communication that require moving through space. Offshoring requires control.

Economic geography in full revival[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

Economic geography has experienced a boom linked to these new challenges and these new demands, but this is also linked to epistemological and theoretical changes that are those of a cultural turning point in economic geography that was taken in the 1990s. For a long time, the world of economics was considered as an autonomous world which had its own logics as logics of rationality with Christaller's model for example which reduced space to a few explanations. This consensus crumbled in the 1980s and emerged from cultural approaches in the 1990s.

The irruption of culture in the economy is linked to the fact that fewer and fewer material goods are being sold and more and more symbolic goods are being sold. In other words, there are more and more symbols in the goods that are sold and the material goods. We make fewer and fewer objects and more and more ideas and that in the objects we make, the utilitarian component is less and less important than the symbolic component which is more and more important. Culture has undoubtedly become the first economic good of the rich countries. There is a phenomenon of tertiarization of industry, while industry is turning more and more to symbol manipulation. This does not necessarily mean that these cultural industries must be analyzed in a new way. When we speak of a cultural turning point, it is the economists themselves with three major trends:

  • a "built-in" economy (Polanyi[1943], Granovetter[1985] and the new economic sociology) (in the social, in space) it is the idea of marking a break with the modes of thought of economists who considered the world of economics as a world apart that one could consider, model and theorize while making abstraction of the context in which it was found. It was economic empowerment. It was possible to understand the functioning of a society by cutting it off from its political functioning or from its spatial functioning, but also from its place in space. Polania and Granovetter have shown that the economy is very deeply embedded in the social and political, there is no need to distinguish the social, political and economic fabric. When we look at the real functioning of the economic and the social, the economy is deeply embedded in the economic and the social. Basically, we couldn't understand it because we were working on a fiction that was free from its social embedded character.
  • heterodox economists (post-autistic economics): there has been the development of heterodox economists who accept and have developed other ways of doing business. These heterodox economists have taken into account the social, the political with the school of conventions, institutional economics, the idea of the market as fiction in particular. This has led to the development of new economic currents taken into account by geographers who have tried to understand to what extent it can be theorized in the framework of understanding space.
  • variety of production and consumption cultures, forms of capitalism ("realistic" epistemology): to understand consumption and production patterns, we must look at reality in the space of the variety of behaviours.

There are essentially three main directions:

  • Space is fundamentally involved in economic processes (Los Angeles school, French school of proximity): the two schools started from the same question which is that whereas transport has never been so cheap, whereas goods are produced more and more material, the economy has never been so concentrated in space with the emergence of industrial districts. The paradigmatic example is the Silicon valley south of San Francisco where Sanford University is located. This district has become the world's hypercentre for production and research in the field, raising the question of why they have all put themselves in the same place. One of the answers is that this information is so sensitive and complex that we need to see each other. Industrial districts are places where a type of production will be concentrated with quite particular production structures. The term Specialized Production District (SPL) is also used. In spatial planning policies, we try to bring out industrial districts. It was this mystery that led to the school's proximity to Los Angeles and French to develop. It is a direction in research that is all the more important because it has a direct impact on development policies.
  • the non-economic components of the economy (modes of regulation, institutions, corporate cultures, consumer cultures, etc.): geographers began to work on objects that were considered as economic objects such as the shopping mall that cannot be understood if it is reduced to an economic object. The shopping mall has become a form of place of sociability.
  • the new geographical economy: Krugman proposes a new theory of international trade and inequality. Unlike the previous two, Krugman is in the liberal economy model. In the major assumptions of the liberal economy, he will drop the hypothesis of pure and perfect competition by emphasizing increasing returns that allows a better understanding of inequalities in development.

Examples[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

San Paolo[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

Geoeco exemple sao paolo plateforme 1.png

A platform has been installed on this building. San Paolo is a huge agglomeration. This building is located in a historical centre. The presence of an internet café probably attests that people do not have internet at home. The internet café shows the potential to be in contact with the whole world for almost no cost, but at the same time it is not.

With this urban landscape, there are like three economic spaces that cohabit:

  • the space of the street;
  • the space of globalization;
  • the space manifested by the office towers and the heliport.

There are incompatibilities between these three types of spaces. Things can't work at the same time. All these scales work at the same time.

The West Indies – Théodore de Bry[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

Geoeco exemple théodore de bry 1.jpg

This engraving of Theodore de Bry shows the arrival of Christopher Columbus in the West Indies. The engraving dates from 1590 about a hundred years after the arrival of Christopher Columbus imagining this encounter. The three caravels of Christopher Columbus appear, the men who land, the urgency is to place a cross since there is the question of evangelization, and then there is power, the army and the flag. The natives are naked because they are savages and it is hot, others flee. The natives give presents.

There is an economic exchange. There are two attitudes among savages with those who run away and those who offer gifts. There is an exchange of wealth that does not pass through the market. There is a unilateral exchange that raises the question of the logic of this exchange. Why is he offering Columbus? They make Christopher Columbus their debtor in exchange for life. The idea is that we try to coax potential attackers by offering them something. Christopher Columbus left to short-circuit the Silk Road and arrive directly in China from the west. The purpose of the trip was purely economic to feed the Hispanic coffers by diverting from the Silk Road. It is possible to make an analysis in terms of economic geography.

Introduction to regional geography – Paul Claval[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

Geoeco exemple ouvrage paul claval 1.jpg

Paul Claval was one of the important thinkers of economic geography. We have the impression that there are two very different types of organization of space. At the bottom of space, we feel a human presence and a very marked artificialisation. The very marked quadrige is not nature, it is an organization of space made by human societies. In the north we do not find this grid, moreover, it is not the same color. At the bottom they are cultivated fields and at the top they are forests.

One has the impression that two cultivated spaces are taken in photography giving the impression of two photos, all the more so as the boundary between the two, there are two rectilinear spaces. Nevertheless, it is only a photo that relates the same space where there is simply a very strong opposition between two different types of economic production.

One of the first explanations may be the climate. The transition from one climate to the other is gradual, there is no reason why it should correspond to such a limit. This image represents the border between the United States and Canada. The explanation is in the political system. We are in a place where there is normally no reason to produce grain because the cost of labour and the nature of the soil is such that it is not profitable. Canada has stopped producing wheat, unlike the United States, which continues to produce grain at a loss. Their interest would be to stop producing wheat and import it. The reason for such production is because it is subsidized. The state will pay the different price.

The reason is not related to a state of mind, soil nature or cold, to the north, it is only forest because wheat is not subsidized. There are several reasons why a country cannot give up its agriculture because a country must be food self-sufficient, because wheat is a weapon, because rural areas are an issue from an identity point of view. There was a time when geography was the constraints of the natural environment. Geography is present in this line which opposes two different structured spaces. There are two different legal and political systems that take place in opposite ways in globalization. Because of its power, the United States is able to impose free trade without applying it itself, unlike Canada. The primary factor explaining this opposition is a strictly economic factor, which is the subsidies paid.

The market in Martinique[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

Geoeco exemple marché martinique 1.png

It's a tourist market. We are in an old market structure that is a metal structure with corrugated posts. It is a late 19th and early 20th century structure which was certainly originally a local market set up by the French administration. The spread of the market economy by the French administration resulted in the establishment of a market to centralize trade at one place with periodicity and control of weight and measures.

If we look at these products, we notice that the different stands present comparable products, but also organized in the same way. You can see that all these shops seem to sell exactly the same thing. Something does not seem rational which on the one hand is selling "made in china" in a Martinican market, on the other hand, the commercial structure of these businesses which all sell the same thing presented in the same way.

The reason why the arrangement is such is probably not because each of these economic actors is selfish, fully rational, informed and seeks to maximize its utility independently of its neighbours. Maybe these actresses are not rational, informed, maybe they seek something other than their utility, maybe they don't decide alone. We have to inject something that is not the homo oeconomicus model into this place of sale, which is the market.

A first explanation is that we are at an early stage of economic development where there are few models, there has not yet been a time for diversification where everyone sets up a different model. Another explanation is that the vendors are not competing to resolve the conflict between these two people. The sharing of the clientele does not depend on the merchants, the clientele will be distributed randomly by the choice of the clients. Competition is cancelled in order to avoid conflicts, but also to maintain prices at a certain level. A third type of explanation would be to say that these stores are owner-owned and the saleswomen are employed, the economic system is such that the saleswomen have no incentive to sell and they are not motivated to make a profit.

In terms of economic geography, two elements are interesting: the transition from one market to another and the explanation of the stands which are all exactly the same.

Annexes[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

References[modifier | modifier le wikicode]