Modification de What is International Political Economy?

Attention : vous n’êtes pas connecté(e). Votre adresse IP sera visible de tout le monde si vous faites des modifications. Si vous vous connectez ou créez un compte, vos modifications seront attribuées à votre propre nom d’utilisateur(rice) et vous aurez d’autres avantages.

La modification peut être annulée. Veuillez vérifier les différences ci-dessous pour voir si c’est bien ce que vous voulez faire, puis publier ces changements pour finaliser l’annulation de cette modification.

Version actuelle Votre texte
Ligne 1 : Ligne 1 :
{{Infobox Lecture
| image =
| image_caption =
| cours = [[International Political Economy]]
| faculté = [[Global Studies Institute]]
| département =
| professeurs = [[Christakis Georgiou]]<ref>[https://www.unige.ch/gsi/fr/presentation/enseignants/cer/christakis-georgiou/ Profil de Christakis Georgiou sur le site de l'Université de Genève]</ref><ref>[https://blogs.mediapart.fr/christakis-georgiou Profil de Christakis Georgiou sur le site de Mediapart]</ref><ref>[https://www.cairn.info/publications-de-Christakis-Georgiou--657762.htm# Publications de Christakis Georgiou sur Cairn.info]</ref><ref>[https://affective-sciences.academia.edu/ChristakisGeorgiou Publications de Christakis Georgiou sur Academia.edu]</ref>
| enregistrement =
| lectures =
* [[What is International Political Economy?]]
* [[A brief history of international capitalism]]
* [[Theories of International Political Economy]]
* [[International trade cooperation]]
* [[Domestic trade politics]]
* [[Politics of preferential trade agreements]]
* [[Multinational corporations and global value chains]]
* [[Political of multinational corporations]]
* [[International monetary cooperation]]
* [[Monetary and exchange rate politics]]
* [[Politics of international financial crises]]
* [[Democracies in globalized economies]]
}}
{{Translations
| fr = Qu'est-ce que l'économie politique internationale ?
| es = ¿Qué es la Economía Política Internacional?
}}
=What is International political economy?=
=What is International political economy?=


Ligne 117 : Ligne 89 :
[[Fichier:Karl Marx 001.jpg|vignette|Karl Marx in 1875.]]
[[Fichier:Karl Marx 001.jpg|vignette|Karl Marx in 1875.]]


The first obvious exception is the Marxists with the project to continue the work of [https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Karl_Marx Karl Marx] on the capital. Marxists authors produced a theory on the way capitalism works as a total social reality and not just as an economic system but as a social order in and of itself. Marx's critical theories about society, economics and politics – collectively understood as Marxism – hold that human societies develop through class struggle. In capitalism, this manifests itself in the conflict between the ruling classes (known as the bourgeoisie) that control the means of production and the working classes (known as the proletariat) that enable these means by selling their labour-power in return for wages.<ref>Marx, K. and Engels, F. (1848).''[https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1848/communist-manifesto/index.htm The Communist Manifesto]''</ref><ref name=":0">Wikipedia contributors. (2020, March 4). Karl Marx. In ''Wikipedia, The Free Encyclopedia''. Retrieved 17:26, March 9, 2020, from https://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=Karl_Marx</ref> Marxism has had a profound impact on global academia and has influenced many fields.<ref>O’Laughlin, B. (1975). Marxist Approaches in Anthropology. Annual Review of Anthropology, 4(1), 341–370. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev.an.04.100175.002013</ref><ref>Roseberry, W. (1997). MARX AND ANTHROPOLOGY. Annual Review of Anthropology, 26(1), 25–46. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev.anthro.26.1.25</ref><ref>Becker, S. L. (1984). Marxist approaches to media studies: The British experience. Critical Studies in Mass Communication, 1(1), 66–80. https://doi.org/10.1080/15295038409360014</ref><ref>Sheehan, H. (2007). Marxism and Science Studies: A Sweep through the Decades. International Studies in the Philosophy of Science, 21(2), 197–210. https://doi.org/10.1080/02698590701498126</ref> The term political economy initially referred to the study of the material conditions of economic production in the capitalist system. In Marxism, political economy is the study of the means of production, specifically of capital and how that manifests as economic activity.<ref name=":0" />
The first obvious exception is the Marxists with the project to continue the work of [https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Karl_Marx Karl Marx] on the capital. Marxists authors produced a theory on the way capitalism works as a total social reality and not just as an economic system but as a social order in and of itself. Marx's critical theories about society, economics and politics – collectively understood as Marxism – hold that human societies develop through class struggle. In capitalism, this manifests itself in the conflict between the ruling classes (known as the bourgeoisie) that control the means of production and the working classes (known as the proletariat) that enable these means by selling their labour-power in return for wages.<ref>Marx, K. and Engels, F. (1848).''[https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1848/communist-manifesto/index.htm The Communist Manifesto]''</ref><ref name=":0">Wikipedia contributors. (2020, March 4). Karl Marx. In ''Wikipedia, The Free Encyclopedia''. Retrieved 17:26, March 9, 2020, from <nowiki>https://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=Karl_Marx</nowiki></ref> Marxism has had a profound impact on global academia and has influenced many fields.<ref>O’Laughlin, B. (1975). Marxist Approaches in Anthropology. Annual Review of Anthropology, 4(1), 341–370. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev.an.04.100175.002013</ref><ref>Roseberry, W. (1997). MARX AND ANTHROPOLOGY. Annual Review of Anthropology, 26(1), 25–46. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev.anthro.26.1.25</ref><ref>Becker, S. L. (1984). Marxist approaches to media studies: The British experience. Critical Studies in Mass Communication, 1(1), 66–80. https://doi.org/10.1080/15295038409360014</ref><ref>Sheehan, H. (2007). Marxism and Science Studies: A Sweep through the Decades. International Studies in the Philosophy of Science, 21(2), 197–210. https://doi.org/10.1080/02698590701498126</ref> The term political economy initially referred to the study of the material conditions of economic production in the capitalist system. In Marxism, political economy is the study of the means of production, specifically of capital and how that manifests as economic activity.<ref name=":0" />


In the Marxist tradition, we can notably cite two key authors. There is [https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Rudolf_Hilferding Rudolf Hilferding] who wrote ''Finance Capital'' (''Das Finanzkapital'') in 1910<ref>Rudolf Hilferding, [https://www.marxists.org/archive/hilferding/1910/finkap/ Finance Capital. A Study of the Latest Phase of Capitalist Development]. Ed. Tom Bottomore (Routledge & Kegan Paul, London, 1981)</ref><ref>Kowalik, T. (2014). Rudolf Hilferding’s Theory of Finance Capital. In Rosa Luxemburg (pp. 131–142). https://doi.org/10.1057/9781137428349_10</ref>, and [https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Rosa_Luxemburg Rosa Luxemburg], who wrote ''[https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/The_Accumulation_of_Capital The Accumulation of Capital]'', first published in 1913, a book about imperialism within which she argues that capitalism needs to constantly expand into noncapitalist areas to access new supply sources, markets for surplus-value, and reservoirs of labor.<ref>Scott, Helen (2008). "Introduction to Rosa Luxemburg". The Essential Rosa Luxemburg: Reform or Revolution and The Mass Strike. By Luxemburg, Rosa. Chicago, IL: Haymarket Books. p. 18.</ref><ref>Wikipedia contributors. (2019, December 18). The Accumulation of Capital. In Wikipedia, The Free Encyclopedia. Retrieved 17:47, March 9, 2020, from https://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=The_Accumulation_of_Capital</ref>  
In the Marxist tradition, we can notably cite two key authors. There is [https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Rudolf_Hilferding Rudolf Hilferding] who wrote ''Finance Capital'' in 1910<ref>Rudolf Hilferding, [https://www.marxists.org/archive/hilferding/1910/finkap/ Finance Capital. A Study of the Latest Phase of Capitalist Development]. Ed. Tom Bottomore (Routledge & Kegan Paul, London, 1981)</ref><ref>Kowalik, T. (2014). Rudolf Hilferding’s Theory of Finance Capital. In Rosa Luxemburg (pp. 131–142). https://doi.org/10.1057/9781137428349_10</ref>, and [https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Rosa_Luxemburg Rosa Luxemburg], who wrote ''[https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/The_Accumulation_of_Capital The Accumulation of Capital]'', first published in 1913, a book about imperialism within which she argues that capitalism needs to constantly expand into noncapitalist areas to access new supply sources, markets for surplus-value, and reservoirs of labor.<ref>Scott, Helen (2008). "Introduction to Rosa Luxemburg". The Essential Rosa Luxemburg: Reform or Revolution and The Mass Strike. By Luxemburg, Rosa. Chicago, IL: Haymarket Books. p. 18.</ref><ref>Wikipedia contributors. (2019, December 18). The Accumulation of Capital. In Wikipedia, The Free Encyclopedia. Retrieved 17:47, March 9, 2020, from https://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=The_Accumulation_of_Capital</ref>  


There is also [https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Vladimir_Lenin Lenin] who published in September 1917 his book ''[https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Imperialism,_the_Highest_Stage_of_Capitalism Imperialism, the Highest Stage of Capitalism]''. Drawing on the economic literature available to him in Zurich and drawing on the works of [https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/J._A._Hobson John Atkinson Hobson] and [https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Rudolf_Hilferding Rudolf Hilferding] on imperialism, Lenin sets out his views on the recent transformations of capitalism and their political consequences in the context of the First World War.<ref>Géraldine Vaughan, Clarisse Berthezene, Pierre Purseigle, Julien Vincent, ''[https://books.google.fr/books?id=H9E1QwAACAAJ&dq=Le+Monde+britannique+1815-1931&hl=en&sa=X&ved=0ahUKEwiq1KL0pY7oAhUHzIUKHTr5AUQQ6AEIQDAC Le Monde britannique 1815-1931, Historiographie, Bibliographie, Enjeux]'', Belin, 2010, p. 11</ref> He argues that imperialism was a product of monopoly capitalism, as capitalists sought to increase their profits by extending into new territories where wages were lower and raw materials cheaper<ref>[https://www.marxists.org/archive/lenin/works/1916/imp-hsc/ Imperialism, the Highest Stage of Capitalism] by Vladimir Lenin at the [https://www.marxists.org/ Marxists Internet Archive]</ref><ref>Wikipedia contributors. (2020, February 24). Imperialism, the Highest Stage of Capitalism. In ''Wikipedia, The Free Encyclopedia''. Retrieved 20:56, March 9, 2020, from https://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=Imperialism,_the_Highest_Stage_of_Capitalism</ref> with imperialism, the highest (advanced) stage of capitalism, requiring monopolies (of labour and natural-resource exploitation) and the exportation of finance capital (rather than goods) to sustain colonialism, which is an integral function of said economic model.<ref>Paul Bowles (2007) ''Capitalism'', Pearson: London. pp. 91–93</ref><ref>[http://www.marxists.org/archive/lenin/works/1916/imp-hsc/ch03.htm ''Imperialism the Highest Stage of Capitalism'' III. Finance Capital and the Financial Oligarchy]</ref> ''Imperialism, the Highest Stage of Capitalism'' became a standard textbook and propelled Lenin has a central figure in the debate about imperialism. Therefore, for the Marxists, imperialism is a structural feature of capitalism.
There is also [https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Vladimir_Lenin Lenin] who published in September 1917 his book ''[https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Imperialism,_the_Highest_Stage_of_Capitalism Imperialism, the Highest Stage of Capitalism]''. Drawing on the economic literature available to him in Zurich and drawing on the works of [https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/J._A._Hobson John Atkinson Hobson] and [https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Rudolf_Hilferding Rudolf Hilferding] on imperialism, Lenin sets out his views on the recent transformations of capitalism and their political consequences in the context of the First World War.<ref>Géraldine Vaughan, Clarisse Berthezene, Pierre Purseigle, Julien Vincent, ''[https://books.google.fr/books?id=H9E1QwAACAAJ&dq=Le+Monde+britannique+1815-1931&hl=en&sa=X&ved=0ahUKEwiq1KL0pY7oAhUHzIUKHTr5AUQQ6AEIQDAC Le Monde britannique 1815-1931, Historiographie, Bibliographie, Enjeux]'', Belin, 2010, p. 11</ref> He argues that imperialism was a product of monopoly capitalism, as capitalists sought to increase their profits by extending into new territories where wages were lower and raw materials cheaper<ref>[https://www.marxists.org/archive/lenin/works/1916/imp-hsc/ Imperialism, the Highest Stage of Capitalism] by Vladimir Lenin at the [https://www.marxists.org/ Marxists Internet Archive]</ref><ref>Wikipedia contributors. (2020, February 24). Imperialism, the Highest Stage of Capitalism. In ''Wikipedia, The Free Encyclopedia''. Retrieved 20:56, March 9, 2020, from <nowiki>https://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=Imperialism,_the_Highest_Stage_of_Capitalism</nowiki></ref> with imperialism, the highest (advanced) stage of capitalism, requiring monopolies (of labour and natural-resource exploitation) and the exportation of finance capital (rather than goods) to sustain colonialism, which is an integral function of said economic model.<ref>Paul Bowles (2007) ''Capitalism'', Pearson: London. pp. 91–93</ref><ref>[http://www.marxists.org/archive/lenin/works/1916/imp-hsc/ch03.htm ''Imperialism the Highest Stage of Capitalism'' III. Finance Capital and the Financial Oligarchy]</ref> ''Imperialism, the Highest Stage of Capitalism'' became a standard textbook and propelled Lenin has a central figure in the debate about imperialism. Therefore, for the Marxists, imperialism is a structural feature of capitalism.


After the war, Marxist theory, to some extent, became subsumed under anti-colonial preoccupations and gave rise to the [https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Dependency_theory dependency theory]. Dependency theory was derived from Listian and Hamiltonian approaches to political economy. This theory was officially developed in the late 1960s following World War II, as scholars searched for the root issue in the lack of development in Latin America.<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Ahiakpor|first=James C. W.|date=1985|title=The Success and Failure of Dependency Theory: The Experience of Ghana|url=http://www.jstor.org/stable/2706689|journal=International Organization|volume=39|issue=3|pages=535–552|issn=0020-8183}}</ref> Dependency theory is, therefore, a Latin American phenomenon mostly because Latin America was the first segment of the old colonial world that became independent in the 19th century and so, theoretically, also was in the vanguard of the anti-colonial struggle.<ref>Wikipedia contributors. (2020, March 6). Dependency theory. In ''Wikipedia, The Free Encyclopedia''. Retrieved 21:22, March 9, 2020, from https://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=Dependency_theory</ref> For the dependency theory, these countries are integrated but are structurally placed in a state of continuous dependency by applying, for example, a ban on domestic production of products to be purchased from colonial companies. For André Gunder Frank, the dependence of the countries of the South can be explained historically by colonization (Asia, Africa, Latin America for example) and by unequal trade (by companies such as the Dutch East India Company or the English East India Company). For the Argentinean economist Raúl Prebisch, the wealth of rich countries is inversely proportional to that of poor countries. For dependency theorists, it is currently impossible for the countries of the South to develop without freeing themselves from the ties of dependency maintained with the North since the development of the countries of the North is based on the underdevelopment of those of the South. <ref>Théorie de la dépendance. (2019, September 3). ''Wikipédia, l'encyclopédie libre''. Page consultée le 01:30, September 3, 2019 à partir de http://fr.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=Th%C3%A9orie_de_la_d%C3%A9pendance</ref>  
After the war, Marxist theory, to some extent, became subsumed under anti-colonial preoccupations and gave rise to the [https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Dependency_theory dependency theory]. Dependency theory was derived from Listian and Hamiltonian approaches to political economy. This theory was officially developed in the late 1960s following World War II, as scholars searched for the root issue in the lack of development in Latin America.<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Ahiakpor|first=James C. W.|date=1985|title=The Success and Failure of Dependency Theory: The Experience of Ghana|url=http://www.jstor.org/stable/2706689|journal=International Organization|volume=39|issue=3|pages=535–552|issn=0020-8183}}</ref> Dependency theory is, therefore, a Latin American phenomenon mostly because Latin America was the first segment of the old colonial world that became independent in the 19th century and so, theoretically, also was in the vanguard of the anti-colonial struggle.<ref>Wikipedia contributors. (2020, March 6). Dependency theory. In ''Wikipedia, The Free Encyclopedia''. Retrieved 21:22, March 9, 2020, from <nowiki>https://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=Dependency_theory</nowiki></ref> For the dependency theory, these countries are integrated but are structurally placed in a state of continuous dependency by applying, for example, a ban on domestic production of products to be purchased from colonial companies. For André Gunder Frank, the dependence of the countries of the South can be explained historically by colonization (Asia, Africa, Latin America for example) and by unequal trade (by companies such as the Dutch East India Company or the English East India Company). For the Argentinean economist Raúl Prebisch, the wealth of rich countries is inversely proportional to that of poor countries. For dependency theorists, it is currently impossible for the countries of the South to develop without freeing themselves from the ties of dependency maintained with the North since the development of the countries of the North is based on the underdevelopment of those of the South. <ref>Théorie de la dépendance. (2019, September 3). ''Wikipédia, l'encyclopédie libre''. Page consultée le 01:30, September 3, 2019 à partir de <nowiki>http://fr.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=Th%C3%A9orie_de_la_d%C3%A9pendance</nowiki></ref>  


So Marxism and dependency theory were one major exception to the way the study of economics and politics was organized in academia after the marginalist revolution.
So Marxism and dependency theory were one major exception to the way the study of economics and politics was organized in academia after the marginalist revolution.
Ligne 151 : Ligne 123 :
Keynes spent a lot of his energy in the 1920s writing political tracts attacking the policies that were pursued by the major powers in Versailles and then their domestic and foreign economic policies. He will notably publish ''A Revision of the Treaty'' in 1922 to advocate a reduction of German reparations and in ''A Tract on Monetary Reform'' published in 1823 he denounces the post-World War I deflation policies.<ref>Skidelsky, Robert Jacob Alexander. "John Maynard Keynes, 1883-1946: economist, philosopher, statesman." (2003).</ref> He was the first in the 1920s to say that the structures of the classical era should not be reproduced because there were shifts in domestic political economies notably arguing against a return to the gold standard at parity as it ran counter to the need for domestic policy autonomy.
Keynes spent a lot of his energy in the 1920s writing political tracts attacking the policies that were pursued by the major powers in Versailles and then their domestic and foreign economic policies. He will notably publish ''A Revision of the Treaty'' in 1922 to advocate a reduction of German reparations and in ''A Tract on Monetary Reform'' published in 1823 he denounces the post-World War I deflation policies.<ref>Skidelsky, Robert Jacob Alexander. "John Maynard Keynes, 1883-1946: economist, philosopher, statesman." (2003).</ref> He was the first in the 1920s to say that the structures of the classical era should not be reproduced because there were shifts in domestic political economies notably arguing against a return to the gold standard at parity as it ran counter to the need for domestic policy autonomy.


Alongside Keynes, there is [https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Jacob_Viner Jacob Viner] who was a Canadian economist in the US Treasury Department during the administration of Franklin Roosevelt, and [https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Charles_P._Kindleberger Charles Kindleberger], an economic historian known for the [https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Hegemonic_stability_theory hegemonic stability theory] and who started his career as an advisor to the US Treasury in the 1940s. Viner is one of the pioneers of theory of the firm, and was the first to distinguish between short-term and long-term cost curves in the article ''Cost curves and supply curves'' published in 1932.<ref>Viner, J. (1932). Cost curves and supply curves. Zeitschrift Für Nationalökonomie, 3(1), 23–46. https://doi.org/10.1007/bf01316299</ref> He was also a notorious opponent of John Maynard Keynes during the Great Depression. For him, Keynes's analysis was containing omissions and would not stand in the long run. As to Kindleberger, is one of the major administrators of the Marshall Plan, the plan that the United States came up with to reconstruct Western Europe after the Second World War. He served as the Acting Director of the Office of Economic Security Policy at the Department of State between 1945 and 1947. Kindleberger is a significant figure in early international political because he wrote the classical analysis of why global capitalism broke down in the 1930s in ''The World in Depression 1929–1939''<ref>Lewis, W. Arthur. The Journal of Interdisciplinary History, vol. 6, no. 1, 1975, pp. 172–174. JSTOR, https://www.jstor.org/stable/202837.</ref> and ''Manias, Panics, and Crashes'' which is the account of the way money and credit mismanagement has contributed to financial crises over centuries.<ref>Kindleberger, Charles P., and Robert Z. Aliber. [https://delong.typepad.com/manias.pdf Manias, panics, and crashes : a history of financial crises]. Hoboken, N.J: John Wiley & Sons, 2005. Print.</ref><ref>“[https://www.economist.com/finance-and-economics/2003/07/17/of-manias-panics-and-crashes Of Manias, Panics and Crashes].” The Economist, The Economist Newspaper, 17 July 2003.</ref><ref>Yuen, Raymond Wai Pong, Book Review – Manias, Panics, and Crashes: A History of Financial Crises 5th Edition (Author of the Book: Charles P. Kindleberger and Robert Aliber) (September 21, 2012). Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2127952 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2127952 </ref> He is also known as the father to the [https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Hegemonic_stability_theory hegemonic stability theory] which is the first major global theory in international political theory that structured the debate. The key idea is that in order for a global economic and political system to work well, there must be a hegemonic power capable of making the necessary decisions to regulate the economy. Therefore, the collapse of an existing hegemon or the state of no hegemon destabilize the international system.<ref>Vincent Ferraro. "The Theory of Hegemonic Stability." http://www.mtholyoke.edu/acad/intrel/pol116/hegemony.htm</ref><ref>Wikipedia contributors. (2020, January 11). Hegemonic stability theory. In Wikipedia, The Free Encyclopedia. Retrieved 19:32, March 10, 2020, from https://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=Hegemonic_stability_theory</ref>
Alongside Keynes, there is [https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Jacob_Viner Jacob Viner] who was a Canadian economist in the US Treasury Department during the administration of Franklin Roosevelt, and [https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Charles_P._Kindleberger Charles Kindleberger], an economic historian known for the [https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Hegemonic_stability_theory hegemonic stability theory] and who started his career as an advisor to the US Treasury in the 1940s. Viner is one of the pioneers of theory of the firm, and was the first to distinguish between short-term and long-term cost curves in the article ''Cost curves and supply curves'' published in 1932.<ref>Viner, J. (1932). Cost curves and supply curves. Zeitschrift Für Nationalökonomie, 3(1), 23–46. https://doi.org/10.1007/bf01316299</ref> He was also a notorious opponent of John Maynard Keynes during the Great Depression. For him, Keynes's analysis was containing omissions and would not stand in the long run. As to Kindleberger, is one of the major administrators of the Marshall Plan, the plan that the United States came up with to reconstruct Western Europe after the Second World War. He served as the Acting Director of the Office of Economic Security Policy at the Department of State between 1945 and 1947. Kindleberger is a significant figure in early international political because he wrote the classical analysis of why global capitalism broke down in the 1930s in ''The World in Depression 1929–1939''<ref>Lewis, W. Arthur. The Journal of Interdisciplinary History, vol. 6, no. 1, 1975, pp. 172–174. JSTOR, https://www.jstor.org/stable/202837.</ref> and ''Manias, Panics, and Crashes'' which is the account of the way money and credit mismanagement has contributed to financial crises over centuries.<ref>Kindleberger, Charles P., and Robert Z. Aliber. [https://delong.typepad.com/manias.pdf Manias, panics, and crashes : a history of financial crises]. Hoboken, N.J: John Wiley & Sons, 2005. Print.</ref><ref>“[https://www.economist.com/finance-and-economics/2003/07/17/of-manias-panics-and-crashes Of Manias, Panics and Crashes].” The Economist, The Economist Newspaper, 17 July 2003.</ref><ref> Yuen, Raymond Wai Pong, Book Review – Manias, Panics, and Crashes: A History of Financial Crises 5th Edition (Author of the Book: Charles P. Kindleberger and Robert Aliber) (September 21, 2012). Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2127952 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2127952 </ref> He is also known as the father to the [https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Hegemonic_stability_theory hegemonic stability theory] which is the first major global theory in international political theory that structured the debate. The key idea is that in order for a global economic and political system to work well, there must be a hegemonic power capable of making the necessary decisions to regulate the economy. Therefore, the collapse of an existing hegemon or the state of no hegemon destabilize the international system.<ref>Vincent Ferraro. "The Theory of Hegemonic Stability." http://www.mtholyoke.edu/acad/intrel/pol116/hegemony.htm</ref><ref>Wikipedia contributors. (2020, January 11). Hegemonic stability theory. In Wikipedia, The Free Encyclopedia. Retrieved 19:32, March 10, 2020, from https://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=Hegemonic_stability_theory</ref>


==Birth of the discipline of International Political Economy==
==Birth of the discipline of International Political Economy==
Ligne 157 : Ligne 129 :
Why was international political economy born in the early 1970s? The first thing is the historical context of the early seventies and how international politics influenced international economy of that time. The economic life of the 1970s was greatly affected by continuously unstable dynamics which resulted in structural changes of the capitalist world economy and notably a change in the dominant policy stance from Keynesianism to neo-conservative monetarism.<ref>Itoh, Makoto. [https://books.google.fr/books?id=G7muCwAAQBAJ&printsec=frontcover&dq=The+World+Economic+Crisis+and+Japanese+Capitalism&hl=en&sa=X&ved=0ahUKEwjClPjV75DoAhVBKBoKHZpAAaAQ6AEIKTAA#v=onepage&q=The%20World%20Economic%20Crisis%20and%20Japanese%20Capitalism&f=false The World Economic Crisis and Japanese Capitalism]. London: Palgrave Macmillan Limited, 1990. Print.</ref>
Why was international political economy born in the early 1970s? The first thing is the historical context of the early seventies and how international politics influenced international economy of that time. The economic life of the 1970s was greatly affected by continuously unstable dynamics which resulted in structural changes of the capitalist world economy and notably a change in the dominant policy stance from Keynesianism to neo-conservative monetarism.<ref>Itoh, Makoto. [https://books.google.fr/books?id=G7muCwAAQBAJ&printsec=frontcover&dq=The+World+Economic+Crisis+and+Japanese+Capitalism&hl=en&sa=X&ved=0ahUKEwjClPjV75DoAhVBKBoKHZpAAaAQ6AEIKTAA#v=onepage&q=The%20World%20Economic%20Crisis%20and%20Japanese%20Capitalism&f=false The World Economic Crisis and Japanese Capitalism]. London: Palgrave Macmillan Limited, 1990. Print.</ref>


The dollar crisis of 1968-1971 and the decision of President Richard Nixon to terminate the convertibility of gold on 15 August 1971 that had been established under the IMF caused the end of the [[Bretton Woods System: 1944 - 1973|Bretton Woods system]].<ref>Strange, Susan. “The Dollar Crisis 1971.” International Affairs (Royal Institute of International Affairs 1944-), vol. 48, no. 2, 1972, pp. 191–216. JSTOR, https://www.jstor.org/stable/2613437.</ref><ref>Diebold, W., & Gowa, J. (1984). Closing the Gold Window: Domestic Politics and the End of Bretton Woods. Foreign Affairs, 63(1), 190. https://doi.org/10.2307/20042113</ref> A dollar standard was then created in December 1971 with the [https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Smithsonian_Agreement Smithsonian Agreement] whereby the currencies of a number of Western countries were fasten to the US dollar.<ref> International Monetary Fund, . (1996). "Chapter 26: Road to the Smithsonian Agreement (August 16–December 18, 1971)". In The International Monetary Fund 1966-1971 : The System Under Stress Volume I: Narrative. USA: INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND. doi: https://doi.org/10.5089/9781451971477.071</ref><ref>Chen, James. “Smithsonian Agreement.” Investopedia, Investopedia, 26 Feb. 2020, https://www.investopedia.com/terms/s/smithsonian-agreement.asp.</ref><ref>Pierce, Francis S., and Roy Forbes Harrod. “The Smithsonian Agreement and After.” Encyclopædia Britannica, Encyclopædia Britannica, Inc., 14 Mar. 2016, https://www.britannica.com/topic/international-payment/The-OECD#ref125864.</ref><ref>Humpage, Owen. “The Smithsonian Agreement.” Federal Reserve History, https://www.federalreservehistory.org/essays/smithsonian_agreement.</ref> The oil crises of 1973 and 1979 resulted in the West to more restrictive monetary policy to better fight inflation. In the 1970s, the so-called Japanese economic miracle took place making Japan a major trading nation and industrial competitors for Western countries. Between 1946 and 1976, Japan sustained economic growth by 55 fold while its exportation known a truly phenomenal growth.<ref>Forsberg, Aaron. [https://books.google.fr/books?id=Lc9FAwAAQBAJ&printsec=frontcover&dq=The+Cold+War+Context+of+Japan%27s+Postwar+Economic+Revival,+1950-1960&hl=en&sa=X&ved=0ahUKEwjg5JTG8ZDoAhWxxoUKHSrFCzYQ6AEIKTAA#v=onepage&q=The%20Cold%20War%20Context%20of%20Japan's%20Postwar%20Economic%20Revival%2C%201950-1960&f=false America and the Japanese miracle: the Cold War context of Japan's postwar economic revival, 1950-1960]. Chapel Hill, NC: University of North Carolina Press, 2000. Print.</ref><ref>Monroe, Wilbur F. “Japan's Economy in the 1970s: Implications for the World.” Pacific Affairs, vol. 45, no. 4, 1972, pp. 508–520. JSTOR, www.jstor.org/stable/2755656.</ref> The movement of exchange rates also increased considerably in the early part of the post-Bretton Woods era.<ref>Makin, John H., and John H. Makin. [https://ies.princeton.edu/pdf/E103.pdf Capital flows and exchange-rate flexibility in the post-Bretton Woods era]. No. 103. International Finance Section, Princeton University, 1974.</ref><ref>Frankel, Jeffrey A., et al. "[https://www.nber.org/chapters/c6221.pdf International capital flows and domestic economic policies]." ''The United States in the world economy''. University of Chicago Press, 1988. 559-658.</ref><ref>Yang, D. (2008). Coping with Disaster: The Impact of Hurricanes on International Financial Flows, 1970-2002. The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy, 8(1). https://doi.org/10.2202/1935-1682.1903</ref> For smaller or more outward-looking economies, the floating exchange rate is disruptive. The same is true for developing countries that are concerned about the floating exchange rate for the stability of their economies. With the transition to the floating exchange rate, some countries of the world and especially countries that claim to compete for the dominance of the international financial market are liberalizing their international capital transactions. The most important changes are taking place in the United States, which is trying to regain ground following the abolition of capital controls and is committed to the liberalisation of the financial sector. For other countries, we see a "back and forth" during the 1970s even with regard to capital flow controls, not to mention the liberalization of their financial sector.<ref>Baripedia. Money, Finance and the World Economy: 1974 - 2000. from https://baripedia.org/w/index.php?title=Money,_Finance_and_the_World_Economy:_1974_-_2000</ref>
The dollar crisis of 1968-1971 and the decision of President Richard Nixon to terminate the convertibility of gold on 15 August 1971 that had been established under the IMF caused the end of the [[Bretton Woods System: 1944 - 1973|Bretton Woods system]].<ref>Strange, Susan. “The Dollar Crisis 1971.” International Affairs (Royal Institute of International Affairs 1944-), vol. 48, no. 2, 1972, pp. 191–216. JSTOR, https://www.jstor.org/stable/2613437.</ref><ref>Diebold, W., & Gowa, J. (1984). Closing the Gold Window: Domestic Politics and the End of Bretton Woods. Foreign Affairs, 63(1), 190. https://doi.org/10.2307/20042113</ref> A dollar standard was then created in December 1971 with the [https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Smithsonian_Agreement Smithsonian Agreement] whereby the currencies of a number of Western countries were fasten to the US dollar.<ref> International Monetary Fund, . (1996). "Chapter 26: Road to the Smithsonian Agreement (August 16–December 18, 1971)". In The International Monetary Fund 1966-1971 : The System Under Stress Volume I: Narrative. USA: INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND. doi: https://doi.org/10.5089/9781451971477.071</ref><ref>Chen, James. “Smithsonian Agreement.” Investopedia, Investopedia, 26 Feb. 2020, https://www.investopedia.com/terms/s/smithsonian-agreement.asp.</ref><ref>Pierce, Francis S., and Roy Forbes Harrod. “The Smithsonian Agreement and After.” Encyclopædia Britannica, Encyclopædia Britannica, Inc., 14 Mar. 2016, https://www.britannica.com/topic/international-payment/The-OECD#ref125864.</ref><ref>Humpage, Owen. “The Smithsonian Agreement.” Federal Reserve History, https://www.federalreservehistory.org/essays/smithsonian_agreement.</ref> The oil crises of 1973 and 1979 resulted in the West to more restrictive monetary policy to better fight inflation. In the 1970s, the so-called Japanese economic miracle took place making Japan a major trading nation and industrial competitors for Western countries. Between 1946 and 1976, Japan sustained economic growth by 55 fold while its exportation known a truly phenomenal growth.<ref>Forsberg, Aaron. [https://books.google.fr/books?id=Lc9FAwAAQBAJ&printsec=frontcover&dq=The+Cold+War+Context+of+Japan%27s+Postwar+Economic+Revival,+1950-1960&hl=en&sa=X&ved=0ahUKEwjg5JTG8ZDoAhWxxoUKHSrFCzYQ6AEIKTAA#v=onepage&q=The%20Cold%20War%20Context%20of%20Japan's%20Postwar%20Economic%20Revival%2C%201950-1960&f=false America and the Japanese miracle: the Cold War context of Japan's postwar economic revival, 1950-1960]. Chapel Hill, NC: University of North Carolina Press, 2000. Print.</ref><ref>Monroe, Wilbur F. “Japan's Economy in the 1970s: Implications for the World.” Pacific Affairs, vol. 45, no. 4, 1972, pp. 508–520. JSTOR, www.jstor.org/stable/2755656.</ref> The movement of exchange rates also increased considerably in the early part of the post-Bretton Woods era.<ref>Makin, John H., and John H. Makin. [https://ies.princeton.edu/pdf/E103.pdf Capital flows and exchange-rate flexibility in the post-Bretton Woods era]. No. 103. International Finance Section, Princeton University, 1974.</ref><ref>Frankel, Jeffrey A., et al. "[https://www.nber.org/chapters/c6221.pdf International capital flows and domestic economic policies]." ''The United States in the world economy''. University of Chicago Press, 1988. 559-658.</ref><ref>Yang, D. (2008). Coping with Disaster: The Impact of Hurricanes on International Financial Flows, 1970-2002. The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy, 8(1). https://doi.org/10.2202/1935-1682.1903</ref> For smaller or more outward-looking economies, the floating exchange rate is disruptive. The same is true for developing countries that are concerned about the floating exchange rate for the stability of their economies. With the transition to the floating exchange rate, some countries of the world and especially countries that claim to compete for the dominance of the international financial market are liberalizing their international capital transactions. The most important changes are taking place in the United States, which is trying to regain ground following the abolition of capital controls and is committed to the liberalisation of the financial sector. For other countries, we see a "back and forth" during the 1970s even with regard to capital flow controls, not to mention the liberalization of their financial sector.<ref>Baripedia. Money, Finance and the World Economy: 1974 - 2000. from https://baripedia.org/w/index.php?title=Money,_Finance_and_the_World_Economy:_1974_-_2000</ref>


<youtube>vNAvsrY9vR4</youtube>  
<youtube>vNAvsrY9vR4</youtube>  
Ligne 165 : Ligne 137 :
The discipline was born independently at the same time both in the United Kingdom and the United States. Of course, the developments in the United States are more relevant and also the course here at the University of Geneva is much more aligned on development in the American trends of international political economy.  
The discipline was born independently at the same time both in the United Kingdom and the United States. Of course, the developments in the United States are more relevant and also the course here at the University of Geneva is much more aligned on development in the American trends of international political economy.  


In the United States, two scholars played a central role in the development of the discipline. Those were [https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Robert_Keohane Robert Keohane] and [https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Joseph_Nye Joseph Nye], the author who notably coined the term soft power in the late 1980s. They were political scientists who were influenced by the functionalists and co-founded the international relations theory of neoliberalism, developed in their 1977 book ''Power and Interdependence''.<ref>Keohane, Robert O., and Joseph S. Nye. ''Power and interdependence''. New York: Longman, 2001. Print.</ref> In the early 1970s, they took over the journal peer-reviewed academic journal [https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/International_Organization_(journal) ''International Organization''] and shifted away its focus from the study of international organizations to the study of international political economy.<ref>“International Organization.” Cambridge Core, https://www.cambridge.org/core/journals/international-organization.</ref><ref>International Organization.” JSTOR, https://www.jstor.org/journal/inteorga</ref> They organized two key conferences, and specifically, that dealt with world politics and the concept of interdependence. After 1975, ''International Organization'' becomes the main outlet for international political economy in the United States.<ref>Jackson, Robert H., Jørgen Møller, and Georg Sørensen. Introduction to international relations : theories and approaches. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2019. Print. [https://books.google.fr/books?id=L2R7DwAAQBAJ&pg=PA202&lpg=PA202&dq=International+Organization+School+keohane+nye&source=bl&ots=ZLVvCRoLCq&sig=ACfU3U1lP01yvdpIOIbMigANa6Om4H_SiA&hl=en&sa=X&ved=2ahUKEwiI9fmyhJLoAhXRDmMBHbChAXcQ6AEwAHoECAUQAQ#v=onepage&q=International%20Organization%20School%20keohane%20nye&f=false page 202]</ref> From then onward, international political economy is more or less identified with the journal to the extent that some people refer to as the American School as the International Organization School.<ref>Maliniak, D., & Tierney, M. J. (2009). The American school of IPE. Review of International Political Economy, 16(1), 6–33. https://doi.org/10.1080/09692290802524042 </ref>
In the United States, two scholars played a central role in the development of the discipline. Those were [https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Robert_Keohane Robert Keohane] and [https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Joseph_Nye Joseph Nye], the author who notably coined the term soft power in the late 1980s. They were political scientists who were influenced by the functionalists and co-founded the international relations theory of neoliberalism, developed in their 1977 book ''Power and Interdependence''.<ref>Keohane, Robert O., and Joseph S. Nye. ''Power and interdependence''. New York: Longman, 2001. Print.</ref> In the early 1970s, they took over the journal peer-reviewed academic journal [https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/International_Organization_(journal) ''International Organization''] and shifted away its focus from the study of international organizations to the study of international political economy.<ref>“International Organization.” Cambridge Core, https://www.cambridge.org/core/journals/international-organization.</ref><ref>International Organization.” JSTOR, https://www.jstor.org/journal/inteorga</ref> They organized two key conferences, and specifically, that dealt with world politics and the concept of interdependence. After 1975, ''International Organization'' becomes the main outlet for international political economy in the United States.<ref> Jackson, Robert H., Jørgen Møller, and Georg Sørensen. Introduction to international relations : theories and approaches. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2019. Print. [https://books.google.fr/books?id=L2R7DwAAQBAJ&pg=PA202&lpg=PA202&dq=International+Organization+School+keohane+nye&source=bl&ots=ZLVvCRoLCq&sig=ACfU3U1lP01yvdpIOIbMigANa6Om4H_SiA&hl=en&sa=X&ved=2ahUKEwiI9fmyhJLoAhXRDmMBHbChAXcQ6AEwAHoECAUQAQ#v=onepage&q=International%20Organization%20School%20keohane%20nye&f=false page 202]</ref> From then onward, international political economy is more or less identified with the journal to the extent that some people refer to as the American School as the International Organization School.<ref>Maliniak, D., & Tierney, M. J. (2009). The American school of IPE. Review of International Political Economy, 16(1), 6–33. https://doi.org/10.1080/09692290802524042 </ref>


Pretty much at the same time, [https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Susan_Strange Susan Strange], who was a professor of international relations in the London School of Economics, played a central role in developing international political economy as a field of study in Britain.<ref>BROWN, C. (1999). Susan Strange—a critical appreciation. Review of International Studies, 25(3), 531–535. https://doi.org/10.1017/s0260210599005318</ref> She notably published in 1970 the article ''International Economics and International Relations: A Case of Mutual Neglect'' which was a kind of manifesto calling for international economists and international political scientists to work together and to try and bridge the gap between international economics (IE) and international relations (IR).<ref>Susan Strange. “[https://www.bu.edu/pardeeschool/files/2018/02/Susan-Strange%E2%80%99s-%E2%80%9CInternational-Economics-and-International-Relations-A-Case-of-Mutual-Neglect.pdf International Economics and International Relations: A Case of Mutual Neglect].” International Affairs (Royal Institute of International Affairs 1944-), vol. 46, no. 2, 1970, pp. 304–315. JSTOR, https://www.jstor.org/stable/2613829.</ref> According to her, scholars from both traditions were neglecting fundamental changes in the world economy arguing that a more modern approach to the study of the global economy was needed. Therefore, for Strange, international political economic was 'middle ground' between economic and political analysis of international affairs.<ref>Cohen, B. J. (2015). A concluding note. Contexto Internacional, 37(3), 1069–1080. https://doi.org/10.1590/s0102-85292015000300010</ref>
Pretty much at the same time, [https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Susan_Strange Susan Strange], who was a professor of international relations in the London School of Economics, played a central role in developing international political economy as a field of study in Britain.<ref>BROWN, C. (1999). Susan Strange—a critical appreciation. Review of International Studies, 25(3), 531–535. https://doi.org/10.1017/s0260210599005318</ref> She notably published in 1970 the article ''International Economics and International Relations: A Case of Mutual Neglec'' which was a kind of manifesto calling for international economists and international political scientists to work together and to try and bridge the gap between international economics (IE) and international relations (IR).<ref>Susan Strange. “[https://www.bu.edu/pardeeschool/files/2018/02/Susan-Strange%E2%80%99s-%E2%80%9CInternational-Economics-and-International-Relations-A-Case-of-Mutual-Neglect.pdf International Economics and International Relations: A Case of Mutual Neglect].” International Affairs (Royal Institute of International Affairs 1944-), vol. 46, no. 2, 1970, pp. 304–315. JSTOR, https://www.jstor.org/stable/2613829.</ref> According to her, scholars from both traditions were neglecting fundamental changes in the world economy arguing that a more modern approach to the study of the global economy was needed. Therefore, for Strange, international political economic was 'middle ground' between economic and political analysis of international affairs.<ref>Cohen, B. J. (2015). A concluding note. Contexto Internacional, 37(3), 1069–1080. https://doi.org/10.1590/s0102-85292015000300010</ref>


==Evolution: American school vs  British school==
==Evolution: American school vs  British school==
Ligne 182 : Ligne 154 :
==Old vs New International Political Economy==
==Old vs New International Political Economy==


American international political economy can be split up into the old and the new international political economy.<ref>Lee, Donna, and David Hudson. “The Old and New Significance of Political Economy in Diplomacy.” Review of International Studies, vol. 30, no. 3, 2004, pp. 343–360. JSTOR, https://www.jstor.org/stable/20097922.</ref><ref>Dickins, Amanda. “The Evolution of International Political Economy.” International Affairs (Royal Institute of International Affairs 1944-), vol. 82, no. 3, 2006, pp. 479–492. JSTOR, https://www.jstor.org/stable/3874263.</ref> The old international political economy based itself on methodologically loose attempts and holistic understandings of the international political economy. From that, the old international political economy of the 1970s gradually moved towards a more positivist and behavioralist direction. From the mid-1980s, international political economy became mainly concerned with positivist explorations of the individual dimensions of the system or with what some authors refer to as Mertonian [https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Middle-range_theory_(sociology) middle-range theory].<ref>Bluedorn, A. C., & Evered, R. (1980). Middle Range Theory and the Strategies of Theory Construction. In Middle Range Theory and the Study of Organizations (pp. 19–32). https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-009-8733-3_2</ref> There is also a shift from qualitative to quantitative methodologies.
American international political economy can be split up into the old and the new international political economy.<ref>Lee, Donna, and David Hudson. “The Old and New Significance of Political Economy in Diplomacy.” Review of International Studies, vol. 30, no. 3, 2004, pp. 343–360. JSTOR, https://www.jstor.org/stable/20097922.</ref><ref>Dickins, Amanda. “The Evolution of International Political Economy.” International Affairs (Royal Institute of International Affairs 1944-), vol. 82, no. 3, 2006, pp. 479–492. JSTOR, https://www.jstor.org/stable/3874263.</ref> The old international political economy based itself on methodologically loose attempts and holistic understandings of the international political economy. From that, the old international political economy of the 1970s gradually moved towards a more positivist and behavioralist direction. From the mid-1980s, international political economy became mainly concerned with positivist explorations of the individual dimensions of the system or with what some authors refer to as Mertonian [https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Middle-range_theory_(sociology) middle-range theory]. There is also a shift from qualitative to quantitative methodologies.


The primary debate in the old international political economy was the debate about complex interdependence, hegemonic stability theory and hegemonic decline. There was a major debate about whether the United States was in hegemonic decline in the late 1970s and 1980s, and another one about international organizations and the governance of the global system. The main focus of the discipline was the international level.
The primary debate in the old international political economy was the debate about complex interdependence, hegemonic stability theory and hegemonic decline. There was a major debate about whether the United States was in hegemonic decline in the late 1970s and 1980s, and another one about international organizations and the governance of the global system. The main focus of the discipline was the international level.
Ligne 197 : Ligne 169 :


=Annexes=
=Annexes=
*Deciancio, M. (2018). La Economía Política Internacional en el campo de las Relaciones Internacionales argentinas. Desafíos, 30(2), 15. https://doi.org/10.12804/revistas.urosario.edu.co/desafios/a.6106
 
*“International Monetary Fund.” International Organization, vol. 1, no. 1, 1947, pp. 124–125. JSTOR, https://www.jstor.org/stable/2703527.
*“International Monetary Fund.” International Organization, vol. 1, no. 1, 1947, pp. 124–125. JSTOR, https://www.jstor.org/stable/2703527.


Notez bien que toutes les contributions à Baripedia sont considérées comme publiées sous les termes de la Attribution-ShareAlike 4.0 International (CC BY-SA 4.0) (voir My wiki:Copyrights pour plus de détails). Si vous ne désirez pas que vos écrits soient modifiés et distribués à volonté, merci de ne pas les soumettre ici.
Vous nous promettez aussi que vous avez écrit ceci vous-même, ou que vous l’avez copié d’une source placée dans le domaine public ou d’une ressource libre similaire. N’utilisez aucun travail sous droits d’auteur sans autorisation expresse !

Pour créer, modifier ou publier cette page, veuillez répondre à la question ci-dessous (plus d’informations) :

Annuler Aide pour la modification (s’ouvre dans une nouvelle fenêtre)

Catégorie cachée dont cette page fait partie :