Modification de Multinational corporations and global value chains

Attention : vous n’êtes pas connecté(e). Votre adresse IP sera visible de tout le monde si vous faites des modifications. Si vous vous connectez ou créez un compte, vos modifications seront attribuées à votre propre nom d’utilisateur(rice) et vous aurez d’autres avantages.

La modification peut être annulée. Veuillez vérifier les différences ci-dessous pour voir si c’est bien ce que vous voulez faire, puis publier ces changements pour finaliser l’annulation de cette modification.

Version actuelle Votre texte
Ligne 1 : Ligne 1 :
International political economy has become an ever-increasingly important topic in the world today. The rise of multinational corporations and global value chains has created a complex system that directly impacts the world’s economy, politics, and culture. Through continued research and analysis of this phenomenon, we can better understand the implications of multinational corporations and global value chains and their effects on the global economy. By looking at the structure, strategies, and operations of multinational corporations and global value chains, we can better understand their influence on the international political economy. These insights can help us to comprehend better the interconnectivity of international markets and the potential impacts of multinational corporations and global value chains on the global economy.
International political economy has become an ever-increasingly important topic in the world today. The rise of multinational corporations and global value chains has created a complex system that directly impacts the world’s economy, politics, and culture. Through continued research and analysis of this phenomenon, we can better understand the implications of multinational corporations and global value chains and their effects on the global economy. By looking at the structure, strategies, and operations of multinational corporations and global value chains, we can better understand their influence on the international political economy. These insights can help us to better comprehend the interconnectivity of international markets and the potential impacts of multinational corporations and global value chains on the global economy.


= Defining Multinational corporation, Foreign direct investment & Global value chain =
= Defining Multinational corporation, Foreign direct investment & Global value chain =
Ligne 33 : Ligne 33 :
During the late 19th and early 20th centuries, MNCs were primarily focused on extracting raw materials and establishing production facilities in developing countries. However, many MNCs also played a role in European powers' colonization of various parts of the world.
During the late 19th and early 20th centuries, MNCs were primarily focused on extracting raw materials and establishing production facilities in developing countries. However, many MNCs also played a role in European powers' colonization of various parts of the world.


After World War II, MNCs began to play a more significant role in the global economy as barriers to international trade and investment began to decline. This period also saw the rise of the United States as a dominant economic power, with many American MNCs establishing operations worldwide.
After World War II, MNCs began to play a more significant role in the global economy as barriers to international trade and investment began to decline. This period also saw the rise of the United States as a dominant economic power, with many American MNCs establishing operations around the world.


In the late 20th and early 21st centuries, MNCs continued to expand their operations globally, often taking advantage of advances in transportation, communication, and information technology to facilitate the flow of goods, services, and capital worldwide. However, the activities of MNCs have also been the subject of controversy and criticism, with some arguing that they contribute to economic inequality and environmental degradation and undermine the sovereignty of host countries.
In the late 20th and early 21st centuries, MNCs continued to expand their operations globally, often taking advantage of advances in transportation, communication, and information technology to facilitate the flow of goods, services, and capital worldwide. However, the activities of MNCs have also been the subject of controversy and criticism, with some arguing that they contribute to economic inequality and environmental degradation and undermine the sovereignty of host countries.
Ligne 41 : Ligne 41 :
During the first global economy period between 1880 and 1929, multinational corporations (MNCs) played a significant role in the global economy. Many MNCs were focused on extracting raw materials and establishing production facilities in developing countries, often with the support of colonial powers. MNCs also played a role in the globalization of financial markets as they sought to raise capital from international investors to fund their operations.
During the first global economy period between 1880 and 1929, multinational corporations (MNCs) played a significant role in the global economy. Many MNCs were focused on extracting raw materials and establishing production facilities in developing countries, often with the support of colonial powers. MNCs also played a role in the globalization of financial markets as they sought to raise capital from international investors to fund their operations.


The rise of MNCs during this period was facilitated by advances in transportation, communication, and other technologies, which made it easier for companies to operate across national borders. MNCs also benefited from declining barriers to international trade and investment and favourable legal and regulatory frameworks in many countries.
The rise of MNCs during this period was facilitated by advances in transportation, communication, and other technologies, which made it easier for companies to operate across national borders. MNCs also benefited from declining barriers to international trade and investment and favorable legal and regulatory frameworks in many countries.


However, the activities of MNCs during this period were subject to controversy. MNCs were often accused of exploiting local resources and labour, contributing to environmental degradation, and undermining the sovereignty of host countries. These issues would continue to be a source of tension and debate in the following decades.
However, the activities of MNCs during this period were subject to controversy. MNCs were often accused of exploiting local resources and labour, contributing to environmental degradation, and undermining the sovereignty of host countries. These issues would continue to be a source of tension and debate in the following decades.
Ligne 120 : Ligne 120 :
Emerging markets, including many countries in East Asia, have experienced strong economic growth in recent years, and this has contributed to an increase in demand for goods and services from these countries. As a result, many multinational corporations (MNCs) have sought to establish or expand operations in these markets to take advantage of the growing opportunities.
Emerging markets, including many countries in East Asia, have experienced strong economic growth in recent years, and this has contributed to an increase in demand for goods and services from these countries. As a result, many multinational corporations (MNCs) have sought to establish or expand operations in these markets to take advantage of the growing opportunities.


Developing countries in East Asia have also become more important players in GVCs, as they have increasingly specialized in producing intermediate goods and services used to produce final goods. This has contributed to the global economy's integration and facilitated the flow of goods, services, and capital worldwide.
Developing countries in East Asia have also become more important players in GVCs, as they have increasingly specialized in producing intermediate goods and services used to produce final goods. This has contributed to the global economy's integration and facilitated the flow of goods, services, and capital around the world.


The distribution of foreign direct investment (FDI) among different regions has changed significantly over the past several decades. According to some estimates, the United States, Europe, and Japan represented around 90% of global FDI flows in the 1980s. This share declined to around 80% between 1990 and 2009 and decreased to around 60% between 2010 and 2016.
The distribution of foreign direct investment (FDI) among different regions has changed significantly over the past several decades. According to some estimates, the United States, Europe, and Japan represented around 90% of global FDI flows in the 1980s. This share declined to around 80% between 1990 and 2009 and decreased to around 60% between 2010 and 2016.


This shift reflects several factors, including the rise of Asian multinational corporations (MNCs) as important foreign investors and the increasing economic importance of developing countries in the global economy. Many Asian MNCs have sought to expand their operations abroad and become major global value chains (GVCs) players. This has contributed to the growing importance of developing countries in the global economy and has led to a shift in the balance of economic power towards these regions.
This shift reflects a number of factors, including the rise of Asian multinational corporations (MNCs) as important foreign investors and the increasing economic importance of developing countries in the global economy. Many Asian MNCs have sought to expand their operations abroad and become major global value chains (GVCs) players. This has contributed to the growing importance of developing countries in the global economy and has led to a shift in the balance of economic power towards these regions.


The changing distribution of FDI among different regions of the world has had important implications for MNCs and other economic actors. It reflects the increasing interdependence of the global economy.
The changing distribution of FDI among different regions of the world has had important implications for MNCs and other economic actors. It reflects the increasing interdependence of the global economy.
Ligne 141 : Ligne 141 :
Regional multinationals, also known as "multilocal" or "regionalized" multinationals, are companies that operate on a global scale but focus on a particular region or geographic area. These companies often have a decentralized organizational structure, with operations and decision-making power being delegated to local subsidiaries in each region. This allows them to tailor their products and services to the specific needs and preferences of the local market while still leveraging the resources and expertise of the global organization. Regional multinationals can be contrasted with "global" multinationals, which have a more centralized organizational structure and tend to standardize their products and operations across different regions.
Regional multinationals, also known as "multilocal" or "regionalized" multinationals, are companies that operate on a global scale but focus on a particular region or geographic area. These companies often have a decentralized organizational structure, with operations and decision-making power being delegated to local subsidiaries in each region. This allows them to tailor their products and services to the specific needs and preferences of the local market while still leveraging the resources and expertise of the global organization. Regional multinationals can be contrasted with "global" multinationals, which have a more centralized organizational structure and tend to standardize their products and operations across different regions.


Alan Rugman's theory of regional multinationals is based on the idea that most multinational corporations (MNCs) are actually regional in scope rather than truly global. According to Rugman, most MNCs operate in a limited number of regions or countries, focusing on serving the specific needs of those markets rather than trying to standardize their operations across the globe.
Alan Rugman's theory of regional multinationals is based on the idea that the majority of multinational corporations (MNCs) are actually regional in scope, rather than truly global. According to Rugman, most MNCs operate in a limited number of regions or countries, focusing on serving the specific needs of those markets rather than trying to standardize their operations across the globe.


In his research, Rugman analyzed firm-level data from the 2011 Fortune Global 500 list and found that 320 out of the 380 companies on the list could be classified as regional MNCs, while only 9 out of the 380 companies could be classified as "global" MNCs. This suggests that most MNCs have a more decentralized, regionally-focused organizational structure and operate in a limited number of regions or countries.
In his research, Rugman analyzed firm-level data from the 2011 Fortune Global 500 list and found that 320 out of the 380 companies on the list could be classified as regional MNCs, while only 9 out of the 380 companies could be classified as "global" MNCs. This suggests that most MNCs have a more decentralized, regionally-focused organizational structure and operate in a limited number of regions or countries.


Most multinational corporations (MNCs) had a regional focus, with 80% of MNCs classified as regional and only 4% classified as global. Additionally, the average score for regional sales and assets for these MNCs was 70% for sales and 72% for assets during the period from 1999-2008.
The majority of multinational corporations (MNCs) had a regional focus, with 80% of MNCs classified as regional and only 4% classified as global. Additionally, the average score for regional sales and assets for these MNCs was 70% for sales and 72% for assets during the period from 1999-2008.


Most multinational corporations (MNCs) from 1999-2008 had a regional focus, with most of their sales and assets concentrated in specific regions or geographic areas. This suggests that these MNCs were primarily focused on serving the needs of local markets rather than trying to standardize their products and operations across the globe.
Most multinational corporations (MNCs) from 1999-2008 had a regional focus, with most of their sales and assets concentrated in specific regions or geographic areas. This suggests that these MNCs were primarily focused on serving the needs of local markets rather than trying to standardize their products and operations across the globe.
Ligne 154 : Ligne 154 :
Multinational corporations (MNCs) exist for a variety of reasons. Some of the primary reasons why MNCs are created and operate include:
Multinational corporations (MNCs) exist for a variety of reasons. Some of the primary reasons why MNCs are created and operate include:


# To access new markets: MNCs may expand into new markets to access new customers and sources of revenue.
# To access new markets: MNCs may expand into new markets in order to access new customers and sources of revenue.
# To take advantage of economies of scale: MNCs can often produce goods and services more efficiently due to their larger scale of operation and may expand into new markets to take advantage of these economies of scale.
# To take advantage of economies of scale: MNCs can often produce goods and services more efficiently due to their larger scale of operation and may expand into new markets to take advantage of these economies of scale.
# To access new sources of raw materials or labour: MNCs may expand into new regions or countries to access cheaper sources of raw materials or labour, which can help reduce their production costs.
# To access new sources of raw materials or labour: MNCs may expand into new regions or countries to access cheaper sources of raw materials or labour, which can help reduce their production costs.
Ligne 167 : Ligne 167 :
One approach that has been widely used to explain the motivations and activities of MNCs is John Dunning's "eclectic theory of international production," which identifies four sets of locational advantages that can drive international expansion:
One approach that has been widely used to explain the motivations and activities of MNCs is John Dunning's "eclectic theory of international production," which identifies four sets of locational advantages that can drive international expansion:


# Natural-resource seeking: MNCs may expand into new markets to access natural resources, such as oil, minerals, or timber, that are not available in their home country.
# Natural-resource seeking: MNCs may expand into new markets in order to access natural resources, such as oil, minerals, or timber, that are not available in their home country.
# Market-seeking: MNCs may expand into new markets to access new customers and sources of revenue.
# Market-seeking: MNCs may expand into new markets to access new customers and sources of revenue.
# Efficiency-seeking: MNCs may expand into new markets to take advantage of lower production costs or other efficiency advantages available in those markets.
# Efficiency-seeking: MNCs may expand into new markets to take advantage of lower production costs or other efficiency advantages available in those markets.
# Strategic-asset seeking: MNCs may expand into new markets to acquire strategic assets, such as technology, intellectual property, or local firms, that can help them improve their competitive position.
# Strategic-asset seeking: MNCs may expand into new markets in order to acquire strategic assets, such as technology, intellectual property, or local firms, that can help them improve their competitive position.


These sets of locational advantages can often overlap and interact with each other, and MNCs may be motivated by multiple factors when making decisions about international expansion.
These sets of locational advantages can often overlap and interact with each other, and MNCs may be motivated by multiple factors when making decisions about international expansion.
Ligne 176 : Ligne 176 :
Another set of alternative explanations for why multinational corporations (MNCs) expand into new markets and engage in cross-border transactions is based on the idea that market imperfections can create incentives for MNCs to expand internationally. These market imperfections can include:
Another set of alternative explanations for why multinational corporations (MNCs) expand into new markets and engage in cross-border transactions is based on the idea that market imperfections can create incentives for MNCs to expand internationally. These market imperfections can include:


# Horizontal integration: MNCs may expand internationally to integrate their operations horizontally, meaning that they can produce a wider range of goods or services in different locations, which can help them capture economies of scale and reduce costs.
# Horizontal integration: MNCs may expand internationally in order to integrate their operations horizontally, meaning that they can produce a wider range of goods or services in different locations, which can help them capture economies of scale and reduce costs.
# Intangible assets: MNCs may have intangible assets, such as brand recognition, intellectual property, or technology, that give them a competitive advantage in certain markets. Expanding internationally can help them leverage these assets and capture additional value.
# Intangible assets: MNCs may have intangible assets, such as brand recognition, intellectual property, or technology, that give them a competitive advantage in certain markets. Expanding internationally can help them leverage these assets and capture additional value.
# Vertical integration: MNCs may expand internationally to integrate their operations vertically, meaning they can control different stages of the production process in different locations. This can help them reduce costs and improve coordination between different parts of the supply chain.
# Vertical integration: MNCs may expand internationally to integrate their operations vertically, meaning they can control different stages of the production process in different locations. This can help them reduce costs and improve coordination between different parts of the supply chain.
Ligne 188 : Ligne 188 :
The global value chain (GVC) concept is a way to understand how international production is organized and how value is added in different locations around the world. It is often used in the context of globalization and the fourth stage of capitalism, characterized by the increasing integration of national economies into the global economy through trade, investment, and other forms of economic exchange.
The global value chain (GVC) concept is a way to understand how international production is organized and how value is added in different locations around the world. It is often used in the context of globalization and the fourth stage of capitalism, characterized by the increasing integration of national economies into the global economy through trade, investment, and other forms of economic exchange.


In the GVC framework, value is created through a series of activities spread across different locations. For example, a product might be designed in one country, manufactured in another, and assembled in a third. Each of these activities represents a different stage in the value chain, and the value of the final product is the sum of the value added at each stage.
In the GVC framework, value is created through a series of activities that are spread out across different locations. For example, a product might be designed in one country, manufactured in another, and assembled in a third. Each of these activities represents a different stage in the value chain, and the value of the final product is the sum of the value added at each stage.


The GVC concept helps to explain how international production is organized and how value is created in the global economy. It also highlights the importance of understanding the relationships between firms and their suppliers and the role of intermediaries such as logistics providers and trade finance institutions.
The GVC concept helps to explain how international production is organized and how value is created in the global economy. It also highlights the importance of understanding the relationships between firms and their suppliers and the role of intermediaries such as logistics providers and trade finance institutions.
Ligne 212 : Ligne 212 :
According to Jennifer Bair, an expert on global value chains (GVCs), the intellectual genealogy of the GVC concept can be traced back to several different sources. These include:
According to Jennifer Bair, an expert on global value chains (GVCs), the intellectual genealogy of the GVC concept can be traced back to several different sources. These include:


# The classical theories of international trade focused on the role of comparative advantage in determining the trade patterns between countries.
# The classical theories of international trade, focused on the role of comparative advantage in determining the trade patterns between countries.
# The work of economist Alfred D. Chandler, Jr., who wrote about the evolution of the multinational corporation (MNC) and the firm's role in organizing international production.
# The work of economist Alfred D. Chandler, Jr., who wrote about the evolution of the multinational corporation (MNC) and the firm's role in organizing international production.
# The world system theories looked at the relationships between core, periphery, and semi-periphery countries and the role of global economic structures in shaping economic development.
# The world system theories looked at the relationships between core, periphery, and semi-periphery countries and the role of global economic structures in shaping economic development.
Ligne 218 : Ligne 218 :
# The work of economists Gary Gereffi and Miguel Korzeniewicz, who developed the concept of GVCs as a way to understand the organization of international production in the global economy.
# The work of economists Gary Gereffi and Miguel Korzeniewicz, who developed the concept of GVCs as a way to understand the organization of international production in the global economy.


The GVC concept has evolved over time, drawing on a range of intellectual traditions and disciplines to provide a comprehensive framework for understanding the global economy.
The GVC concept has evolved over time, drawing on a range of intellectual traditions and disciplines in order to provide a comprehensive framework for understanding the global economy.


The world-system tradition is a framework for analyzing the global division of labour and the patterns of trade and production that have emerged since the emergence of capitalism. This tradition is characterized by a focus on macro-level and long-range historical analysis, and it has influenced our understanding of the organization of the global economy.
The world-system tradition is a framework for analyzing the global division of labour and the patterns of trade and production that have emerged since the emergence of capitalism. This tradition is characterized by a focus on macro-level and long-range historical analysis, and it has influenced our understanding of the organization of the global economy.
Ligne 226 : Ligne 226 :
The world-system tradition has also been influential in developing the concept of commodity chains, which describe the networks of production, trade, and distribution that link together different countries and regions worldwide. The global division of labour, which refers to the way that different countries specialize in different stages of the production process, is a key feature of commodity chains and has been a central focus of research within the world-system tradition.
The world-system tradition has also been influential in developing the concept of commodity chains, which describe the networks of production, trade, and distribution that link together different countries and regions worldwide. The global division of labour, which refers to the way that different countries specialize in different stages of the production process, is a key feature of commodity chains and has been a central focus of research within the world-system tradition.


The global commodity chains (GCC) framework was developed by Gary Gereffi, a sociologist and economist, in the mid-1990s. It is a blend of organizational sociology and comparative development studies. It is designed to provide a comprehensive framework for understanding the organization of international production and the global division of labour.
The global commodity chains (GCC) framework was developed by Gary Gereffi, a sociologist and economist, in the mid-1990s. It is a blend of organizational sociology and comparative development studies. It is designed to provide a comprehensive framework for understanding the organization of international production and the global division of labor.


The GCC framework is based on global value chains (GVCs), which describe the production, trade, and distribution networks that link together countries and regions worldwide. According to Gereffi, GVCs are characterized by a series of activities, such as design, production, and distribution, that are spread out across different locations and that add value to a final product.
The GCC framework is based on global value chains (GVCs), which describe the production, trade, and distribution networks that link together countries and regions worldwide. According to Gereffi, GVCs are characterized by a series of activities, such as design, production, and distribution, that are spread out across different locations and that add value to a final product.
Ligne 239 : Ligne 239 :


== Typology ==
== Typology ==
The global commodity chain framework analyses the global economy's production, distribution, and consumption of goods and services. It highlights the various stages of production that a commodity goes through, from raw materials to final consumption, and the complex network of economic, social, and political relationships that link these stages. The framework examines the various actors involved in the global economy, including multinational corporations, states, labour unions, and other organizations, and how they interact to produce, distribute, and consume goods and services. The global commodity chain framework can analyze various commodities, including manufactured goods, agricultural products, and natural resources, and examine globalisation's impacts on economic development, labour markets, and the environment.
The global commodity chain framework analyses the global economy's production, distribution, and consumption of goods and services. It highlights the various stages of production that a commodity goes through, from raw materials to final consumption, and the complex network of economic, social, and political relationships that link these stages. The framework examines the various actors involved in the global economy, including multinational corporations, states, labour unions, and other organizations, and how they interact to produce, distribute, and consume goods and services. The global commodity chain framework can analyze a wide range of commodities, including manufactured goods, agricultural products, and natural resources, and examine globalisation's impacts on economic development, labour markets, and the environment.


The global commodity chain (GCC) framework, developed by economist Gary Gereffi, analyses the global economy's production, distribution, and consumption of goods and services. It emphasizes the role of firms and their activities in producing goods and services rather than the overall dynamics of capitalism. Gereffi argues that the GCC framework is a more useful way of understanding the global economy than the world-systems perspective, which focuses on the overall dynamics of capitalism and the interactions between core, semi-peripheral, and peripheral regions.
The global commodity chain (GCC) framework, developed by economist Gary Gereffi, analyses the global economy's production, distribution, and consumption of goods and services. It emphasizes the role of firms and their activities in producing goods and services rather than the overall dynamics of capitalism. Gereffi argues that the GCC framework is a more useful way of understanding the global economy than the world-systems perspective, which focuses on the overall dynamics of capitalism and the interactions between core, semi-peripheral, and peripheral regions.
Ligne 257 : Ligne 257 :
Buyer-driven commodity chains (BDCCs) are more common in consumer goods industries and retail, where the firms at the end of the chain have a strong bargaining position due to their ability to specify the requirements of the products and their access to technology and capital. In addition, in these industries, the firms at the end of the chain are often able to exert a high level of control over the production process and the terms of trade due to their ability to set the standards and specifications for the products being produced and their access to consumer markets.
Buyer-driven commodity chains (BDCCs) are more common in consumer goods industries and retail, where the firms at the end of the chain have a strong bargaining position due to their ability to specify the requirements of the products and their access to technology and capital. In addition, in these industries, the firms at the end of the chain are often able to exert a high level of control over the production process and the terms of trade due to their ability to set the standards and specifications for the products being produced and their access to consumer markets.


One example of a firm that is often cited as having a significant role in shaping a BDCC is Walmart. As one of the world's largest retailers, Walmart can specify the requirements for the products it sells and negotiate directly with suppliers to ensure that these requirements are met. This gives it a strong bargaining position in the commodity chain and allows it to exert a high level of control over the production process and the terms of trade. However, it is important to note that not all consumer goods industries or retail firms will necessarily have a BDCC structure, and various factors can influence the specific structure of a commodity chain.
One example of a firm that is often cited as having a significant role in shaping a BDCC is Walmart. As one of the world's largest retailers, Walmart can specify the requirements for the products it sells and negotiate directly with suppliers to ensure that these requirements are met. This gives it a strong bargaining position in the commodity chain, and allows it to exert a high level of control over the production process and the terms of trade. However, it is important to note that not all consumer goods industries or retail firms will necessarily have a BDCC structure, and various factors can influence the specific structure of a commodity chain.


The binary typology of producer-driven versus buyer-driven commodity chains (PDCCs and BDCCs) has been criticized for oversimplifying the complex governance structures within a commodity chain. While the typology is useful for highlighting the different power dynamics within a commodity chain, it can also obscure some of the more nuanced and diverse governance structures that may be present.
The binary typology of producer-driven versus buyer-driven commodity chains (PDCCs and BDCCs) has been criticized for oversimplifying the complex governance structures within a commodity chain. While the typology is useful for highlighting the different power dynamics within a commodity chain, it can also obscure some of the more nuanced and diverse governance structures that may be present.


One criticism of the typology is that it tends to emphasize the role of firms at the beginning and end of the chain while downplaying the importance of other actors such as labour unions, states, and civil society organizations. These actors can have a significant influence on the governance of a commodity chain and may be able to challenge or mitigate the power of firms at the beginning or end of the chain.
One criticism of the typology is that it tends to emphasize the role of firms at the beginning and end of the chain while downplaying the importance of other actors such as labour unions, states, and civil society organizations. These actors can have a significant influence on the governance of a commodity chain, and may be able to challenge or mitigate the power of firms at the beginning or end of the chain.


Another criticism of the typology is that it tends to be static, focusing on the governance structure at a single point rather than considering how it may change over time. However, the governance structure of a commodity chain can be influenced by various factors, including technological change, shifts in the global economy, and the actions of various actors. Over time, a commodity chain can change from producer-driven to buyer-driven (or vice versa).
Another criticism of the typology is that it tends to be static, focusing on the governance structure at a single point rather than considering how it may change over time. However, the governance structure of a commodity chain can be influenced by various factors, including technological change, shifts in the global economy, and the actions of various actors. Over time, a commodity chain can change from producer-driven to buyer-driven (or vice versa).
Ligne 277 : Ligne 277 :
In their 2005 paper, "The Governance of Global Value Chains," economists Gary Gereffi, John Humphrey, and Timothy Sturgeon proposed a typology of network governance structures based on the degree of integration and coordination between firms. They identified five types of governance structures:
In their 2005 paper, "The Governance of Global Value Chains," economists Gary Gereffi, John Humphrey, and Timothy Sturgeon proposed a typology of network governance structures based on the degree of integration and coordination between firms. They identified five types of governance structures:


# Market: This is the most decentralized form of governance, in which firms rely on arm's-length markets to coordinate their activities. There is little integration or coordination between firms, and they operate independently. The transactions in this market are easy to codify, meaning that they can be easily recorded and tracked. The products or services offered in this market have simple specifications, making it easy for buyers and sellers to understand and agree to the terms of a transaction. Additionally, this market has low asset specificity levels, meaning that the assets used in production are not highly specialized and can be used in other industries. There are also low levels of opportunism and coordination costs, indicating that the market is relatively stable and efficient.
# Market: This is the most decentralized form of governance, in which firms rely on arm's-length markets to coordinate their activities. There is little integration or coordination between firms, and they operate independently. The transactions in this market are easy to codify, meaning that they can be easily recorded and tracked. The products or services offered in this market have simple specifications, making it easy for buyers and sellers to understand and agree on the terms of a transaction. Additionally, this market has low levels of asset specificity, which means that the assets used in production are not highly specialized and can be used in other industries. There is also low levels of opportunism and coordination costs, indicating that the market is relatively stable and efficient.
# Captive: This is a more centralized form of governance in which one firm (typically a buyer) has a high level of control over the production process and can dictate the terms of trade. The other firms in the value chain are captive to the dominant firm and must follow its instructions. Captive value chains refer to the organization of production processes in which the transactions, product specifications and supplier capabilities are highly complex and cannot be easily codified or standardized. These value chains are characterized by a dominant firm, known as the lead firm, that exerts tight control over the production process and relies on a limited number of suppliers that have limited capabilities. In these value chains, the lead firm is responsible for the product's design, development, and production, and the suppliers play a more limited role. The lead firm is often highly specialized and deeply understands the production process and the customer's specific needs. Because the product specifications and production process are highly complex, the lead firm may need to exert tight control over the suppliers to ensure that the product is produced to the required specifications. An example of this is in the aerospace and defence industry, where the products are highly complex and require a high degree of specialization. The lead firm in this industry, such as Boeing or Airbus, exert tight control over the suppliers responsible for producing the components and subsystems. This tight control is necessary to ensure that the components and subsystems are produced to the required specifications and meet the safety and reliability requirements of the final product. This model is efficient in quality control but also creates a dependency on the lead firm, which can reduce supplier bargaining power, limit innovation and raise transaction costs. It also can increase risks associated with supply chain disruption.
# Captive: This is a more centralized form of governance in which one firm (typically a buyer) has a high level of control over the production process and can dictate the terms of trade. The other firms in the value chain are captive to the dominant firm and must follow its instructions.
# Relational: This is a more cooperative form of governance in which firms develop long-term relationships and work together to coordinate their activities. There is a high degree of trust and mutual dependence between firms, and they may share risks and rewards. Relational value chains refer to the organization of production processes in which the transactions and product specifications are complex and not easily codified or standardized. In these value chains, suppliers play a critical role, and the coordination of production activities depends on close relationships and trust between the different actors. An example of this is in the apparel industry, where garments' design, development, and production are highly dependent on close relationships between designers, manufacturers, and suppliers. The design of a garment is often based on the designer's creative input, and the final product is often customized to meet the customer's specific needs. Product specifications may need to be more easily codified, and the production process is often highly dependent on the skills and expertise of the suppliers. The close relationships and trust between the different actors in the value chain allow for more efficient communication, more effective problem-solving, and better coordination of production activities. Additionally, it also allows for fast product development, innovation, and adaptation to customers' changing needs. Trust-based relationships can also offer supplier-buyer collaboration in product design, development, and production, leading to a more efficient, effective, and sustainable supply chain. However, the downside of this model is that it may limit the number of suppliers and make it difficult to enter the market, and in case of any breach of trust, it can lead to supply chain disruptions.
# Relational: This is a more cooperative form of governance in which firms develop long-term relationships and work together to coordinate their activities. There is a high degree of trust and mutual dependence between firms, and they may share risks and rewards.
# Modular: This is a more flexible form of governance in which firms specialize in specific tasks and work in a modular fashion, using just-in-time production and other forms of coordination. The firms in the value chain have a high degree of interdependence, but there is also a high degree of competition. Modular value chains refer to the organization of production processes in which the specifications of complex products and components can be easily codified and standardized. This allows for separating the design, development, and production of different parts or modules of a product. These modules can then be easily combined to create various end products. An example of this is in the consumer electronics industry, where companies design and produce modular components such as CPUs, RAM, displays, and cameras that can be used in various devices such as smartphones, laptops, and tablets. This allows for a high degree of standardization and interchangeability among the components and makes it relatively easy for companies to enter and exit the market. This also allows for faster product development and innovation, as different components can be developed in parallel and then integrated to create new and improved products. Modularity can also increase the supply chain's flexibility and adaptability, improve the production process's efficiency and effectiveness, and reduce the risks and costs associated with product development and innovation.
# Modular: This is a more flexible form of governance in which firms specialize in specific tasks and work in a modular fashion, using just-in-time production and other forms of coordination. The firms in the value chain have a high degree of interdependence, but there is also a high degree of competition.
# Hierarchy: This is the most centralized form of governance, in which one firm (typically a producer) has a high level of control over the production process and can dictate the terms of trade. The other firms in the value chain are integrated into the dominant firm's operations and operate as subsidiaries. Hierarchical value chains refer to the organization of production processes in which the transactions, product specifications and supplier capabilities are highly complex and cannot be easily codified or standardized. These value chains are characterized by a dominant firm, known as the lead firm, that internalizes the production of the product rather than relying on external suppliers. In these value chains, the lead firm is responsible for the product's design, development, and production and does not rely on external suppliers to produce the product. The lead firm is highly specialized, has a deep understanding of the production process and the customer's specific needs, and has the necessary capabilities to produce the product internally. Because the product specifications and production process are highly complex, the lead firm may need help finding competent external suppliers to produce the product to the required specifications. An example of this is in the aerospace and defence industry, where the products are highly complex and require a high degree of specialization. As a result, lead firms in this industry, such as Boeing or Airbus, internalize the production of most components and subsystems rather than relying on external suppliers. This internalization is necessary to ensure that the products are produced to the required specifications and meet the safety and reliability requirements of the final product. This model is efficient in terms of quality control and minimizes risks associated with supply chain disruptions. Still, it may lead to high costs and a lack of flexibility and innovation. It also limits the number of suppliers and makes it difficult to enter the market.
# Hierarchy: This is the most centralized form of governance, in which one firm (typically a producer) has a high level of control over the production process and can dictate the terms of trade. The other firms in the value chain are integrated into the dominant firm's operations and operate as subsidiaries.


This typology highlights the diversity of governance structures within a global value chain and how they can vary regarding their degree of integration and coordination.
This typology highlights the diversity of governance structures within a global value chain and how they can vary regarding their degree of integration and coordination.
=== Two general observations ===
Value chains have become increasingly globalized in recent years, leading to a phenomenon known as Global Value Chains (GVCs). There are two general observations about GVCs that are worth mentioning.
There has been a general trend in recent years of increasing supplier capabilities in developing countries due to economic upgrading and development. This trend has led to a shift in the organization of Global Value Chains (GVCs) away from hierarchical and captive networks and towards more relational, modular, and market forms.
As developing countries become more economically advanced, their firms have become more capable of producing higher-value-added goods and services. This has led to a rise in offshoring, as companies in developed countries have begun to outsource production to developing countries to take advantage of lower labour costs and access new markets.
This has led to a rise in standardization as companies have sought to take advantage of the growing capabilities of suppliers in developing countries. Standardization makes producing and trading goods and services easier, allowing firms to enter new markets and expand their operations.
This trend has brought opportunities and challenges. On the one hand, it can lead to economic growth and development in developing countries and create new business opportunities and efficiencies for companies in developed countries. But, on the other hand, it also leads to increased competition. It can negatively impact firms that cannot adapt to these changes and create social and environmental challenges in the locales where the GVCs are being developed.
As standards, information technology, and suppliers' capabilities improve, the modular form of organizing value chains plays an increasingly central role in the global economy. The modular form of value chains separates the design, development, and production of different parts or modules of a product, which can then be combined to create a wide variety of end products.
For example, the increasing use of information technology and automation has allowed for better communication and coordination between firms in different countries. It has made it easier to standardize the specifications of products and components. Additionally, as suppliers' capabilities in developing countries improve, they have become more capable of producing higher-value-added goods and services, which has led to a rise in offshoring and increased demand for modular components.
As a result, the modular form of value chains is becoming increasingly prevalent in the global economy, particularly in consumer electronics, automobiles, and machinery, where product design and development can be separated from production. This increased prevalence of modular value chains allows for more efficient and effective production processes and can also lead to more rapid product development and innovation. However, as with all forms of global value chains, it can also bring sustainability, fair trade and labour rights challenges.
A positive assessment of the economic effects of globalization is often associated with the liberal view. This view holds that globalization has brought significant economic benefits to the world, including increased trade and investment, higher economic growth, and greater prosperity. According to this perspective, globalization has increased efficiency and productivity, as companies can access new markets, customers, and resources. This increased access to markets and resources leads to increased competition, leading to greater innovation and more efficient allocation of resources.
Globalization has also led to greater integration of economies and increased cross-border trade and investment. This has facilitated the transfer of knowledge, technology, and capital between countries, allowing for the developing of new industries and improving existing ones.
Open trade and investment can also lead to greater economic growth and development in developing countries. As developing countries become more integrated into the global economy, they have access to new markets and new sources of capital, which can lead to increased economic growth and development.
=== Recent developments ===
In 2014, Gary Gereffi, a sociologist and economist, published an article titled "Global Value Chains in a Post-Washington Consensus World." In this article, Gereffi examines how global value chains (GVCs) have changed in the wake of the global financial crisis of 2008 and the shifts in economic power that have occurred.
The Washington Consensus, a term coined by economist John Williamson in 1989, refers to a set of economic policy prescriptions that were promoted by the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and World Bank as the best way to promote economic growth and development in developing countries. This consensus included policies such as fiscal austerity, liberalization of trade and investment, and privatization of state-owned enterprises. However, Gereffi argues that the global financial crisis of 2008 and the rise of new economic powers, such as China and Brazil, have shifted away from the Washington Consensus.
Gereffi argues that the rise of new economic powers has led to a shift in the organization of GVCs. The traditional model, where developed countries were the lead firms and developing countries were primarily engaged in low-value-added assembly and manufacturing activities, is no longer the dominant model. Instead, developing countries are increasingly becoming lead firms and are moving up the value chain to engage in more sophisticated activities such as design and R&D.
Additionally, Gereffi argues that the crisis has led to a renewed focus on industrial policy and national innovation systems. Developing countries are now more interested in developing their capabilities and moving up the value chain, rather than relying on foreign investment and technology transfer.
In conclusion, Gereffi suggests that changes in global economic power and policy priorities have led to a new model of GVCs characterized by greater participation and leadership of developing countries in GVCs, and more focus on developing local capabilities and innovation systems.
Since the global financial crisis of 2008, large emerging economies have become less dependent on export-oriented industrialization (EOI) and more inward-looking, with a growing share of domestic demand and a growing share of global production. This trend is driven by several factors, including the emergence of new economic powers, such as China and Brazil, which have proliferated and become major producers and consumers of goods and services, and the changing policy priorities of these countries.
In the wake of the financial crisis, many large emerging economies have shifted their focus from exporting to domestic consumption to sustain economic growth and reduce dependence on exports. This has led to an increase in domestic demand, leading to a growing share of global production. As a result, these economies have become less dependent on exports and more focused on domestic production, which has led to a shift in the organization of global value chains (GVCs).
Additionally, these economies are becoming more self-sufficient in technology, research and development. As a result, they are increasing their focus on developing their capabilities to move up the value chain. This has led to increased participation and leadership of these economies in GVCs.
It is also worth mentioning that this trend is not exclusive to large emerging economies, as countries of all income levels have increased efforts to promote self-sufficiency and localization in strategic sectors, such as semiconductors and technology, to reduce their dependencies on the global market and supply chains.
In recent years, there has been a growing consolidation among suppliers in global value chains (GVCs). This refers to the merger and acquisition of suppliers by other suppliers or lead firms, resulting in fewer but larger suppliers.
Consolidation among suppliers can reduce the asymmetry of power relations between lead firms and suppliers. When there are fewer suppliers in the market, they tend to have more bargaining power and can negotiate better terms with lead firms. This can also lead to increased competition between suppliers and efficiency in production and costs.
On the other hand, this process can also have negative effects, such as reduced choice for lead firms, reduced competition, reduced innovation and increased concentration, which can lead to a less dynamic market. Additionally, it can increase suppliers' vulnerabilities, particularly in terms of dependency and lack of alternative options in case of disputes or other problems.
Additionally, it can lead to negative social and environmental impacts as the consolidation can lead to the closure of smaller suppliers, loss of jobs, and reduced access to goods and services for local communities.
There has been a trend of geographic concentration of global value chain (GVC) activities in proximity to emerging markets and a rise of some emerging market lead firms. Several factors, including the growing demand for goods and services in these markets, the availability of lower-cost labour and resources, and the increasing capabilities of firms in these markets drive this.
Geographic concentration in proximity to emerging markets refers to the clustering of production and other GVC activities in regions close to these markets. This is driven by the need to be close to the source of demand for goods and services and to take advantage of lower costs and increased efficiency that come with proximity.
Additionally, a rise of some emerging market lead firms refers to the increasing participation and leadership of firms from emerging markets in GVCs. This is driven by these firms' growing economic power and capabilities, which can now compete with established lead firms from developed countries in design, innovation, and production.
This trend has brought economic growth and development opportunities in emerging markets, creating new jobs, increased productivity and a higher standard of living. But, on the other hand, it also poses challenges such as increased competition and pressure on wages, working conditions and environmental standards for firms in developed countries.
It is worth mentioning that this trend is common to certain emerging markets, as many countries are looking for ways to tap into these opportunities, such as China and India. Furthermore, as these firms grow and become lead firms in the GVCs, they in turn become the source of demand for other countries, leading to a dynamic and constantly evolving global economy.
In summary, large emerging economies have undergone a significant shift in their economic development strategy since the global financial crisis of 2008, becoming less dependent on exports to developed countries and more focused on domestic consumption and production. Various factors have driven this trend, including the emergence of new economic powers, policy priorities changes, and technology and standards improvements.
These economies are becoming more self-sufficient and independent, moving away from the traditional model of export-oriented industrialization (EOI) and towards a more inward-looking approach. This shift leads to a growing share of domestic demand and global production and is also characterized by an increased focus on developing local capabilities and innovation systems.
Additionally, large emerging economies are becoming more important poles of economic development in the world, driving demand for goods and services and attracting investment from other countries. This trend is also leading to a geographic concentration of GVC activities in proximity to these economies, as well as a rise of some emerging market lead firms, which are now able to compete with established lead firms from developed countries in terms of design, innovation, and production.
= Conclusion =
The role of Multinational Corporations (MNCs) and Global Value Chains (GVCs) in the global economy highlight that national economies are not separate entities in global capitalism but accounting units. In reality, production is cross-border in a qualitatively different way than during the first wave of globalization.
MNCs are companies that operate in multiple countries and can coordinate activities across borders. They are often the lead firms in GVCs and can organize production and trade across multiple countries. This means that the boundaries of production and the ownership of assets are often blurred, and the distinction between domestic and foreign production is becoming increasingly difficult to identify.
Furthermore, GVCs are composed of a network of firms, suppliers, and intermediaries dispersed across different countries and connected by flows of goods, services, information, and capital. This means that the production process is fragmented and spread across different countries, and the value added at each stage of the chain is often located in different countries.
As a result, the distinction between national and foreign production becomes increasingly blurred, and the traditional concept of the "national economy" as a self-contained unit becomes less relevant. This highlights the interdependence and interconnectedness of economies and production processes in the current global economy. This also challenges policymakers, as traditional policy instruments and regulations may need to be more effective in this new reality. It may require new ways of thinking and new policy approaches to address this new economic reality.
The cross-border nature of production in GVCs and the role of MNCs can have significant political implications, particularly in host countries. One implication is that it can affect the ability of host countries to implement trade and public policies.
The cross-border nature of production can make it difficult for host countries to implement trade policies that protect domestic industries, as production processes are often spread across multiple countries. This can limit the effectiveness of traditional trade policy tools such as tariffs and import quotas. It also means that even if a host country wants to implement protectionist policies, it may need help effectively, as production processes have become increasingly integrated and interconnected.
Additionally, the role of MNCs can also affect the ability of host countries to implement public policies, particularly in areas such as labor, environmental and intellectual property rights. MNCs have significant economic power and can often pressure host governments to weaken or water down regulations in these areas. This can make it difficult for host countries to implement policies that protect workers, the environment and promote sustainable development.
Another implication could be the effect on the sovereignty and democratic decision-making of host countries. As transnational actors, MNCs might act in their self-interests rather than in alignment with the host country's laws, values and goals. This can lead to the erosion of the ability of host countries to make decisions that reflect the wishes of their citizens, and can also lead to an erosion of democratic governance and accountability.
It is important to mention that it is sometimes negative, as MNCs can bring positive benefits such as access to finance, new technologies, know-how and jobs to the host countries.
In conclusion, the cross-border nature of production in GVCs and the role of MNCs can have significant political implications, particularly in host countries. These implications can affect the ability of host countries to implement trade and public policies. They can also affect the sovereignty and democratic decision-making of host countries. Therefore, it is important to understand these implications and consider them in the trade and public policy design.


= Annexes =
= Annexes =
Notez bien que toutes les contributions à Baripedia sont considérées comme publiées sous les termes de la Attribution-ShareAlike 4.0 International (CC BY-SA 4.0) (voir My wiki:Copyrights pour plus de détails). Si vous ne désirez pas que vos écrits soient modifiés et distribués à volonté, merci de ne pas les soumettre ici.
Vous nous promettez aussi que vous avez écrit ceci vous-même, ou que vous l’avez copié d’une source placée dans le domaine public ou d’une ressource libre similaire. N’utilisez aucun travail sous droits d’auteur sans autorisation expresse !

Pour créer, modifier ou publier cette page, veuillez répondre à la question ci-dessous (plus d’informations) :

Annuler Aide pour la modification (s’ouvre dans une nouvelle fenêtre)