Modification de Domestic trade politics

Attention : vous n’êtes pas connecté(e). Votre adresse IP sera visible de tout le monde si vous faites des modifications. Si vous vous connectez ou créez un compte, vos modifications seront attribuées à votre propre nom d’utilisateur(rice) et vous aurez d’autres avantages.

La modification peut être annulée. Veuillez vérifier les différences ci-dessous pour voir si c’est bien ce que vous voulez faire, puis publier ces changements pour finaliser l’annulation de cette modification.

Version actuelle Votre texte
Ligne 256 : Ligne 256 :


=== 1919-1939 ===
=== 1919-1939 ===
From 1945 to 1994, the United States experienced significant economic, social, and political changes. The country emerged from World War II as a global economic superpower, and the economy grew rapidly during this period. However, the factor endowments of the period were still characterized by abundant land and scarce capital and labour. However, mobility increased significantly as transportation and communication technologies continued to improve.
From 1945 to 1994, the United States experienced significant economic, social, and political changes. The country emerged from World War II as a global economic superpower, and the economy grew rapidly during this period. However, the factor endowments of the period were still characterized by abundant land and scarce capital and labour. However, mobility increased significantly as transportation and communication technologies continued to improve.


During this time, class-based parties and associations played a significant role in American political and social life. Labour unions and other organisations representing the interests of working people became more prominent and influential, and they often aligned with political parties that supported their goals. The Republican Party, in particular, was seen as more sympathetic to business and industry concerns. At the same time, the Democratic Party was more closely aligned with labour and other working-class interests.
During this time, class-based parties and associations played a significant role in American political and social life. Labour unions and other organisations representing the interests of working people became more prominent and influential, and they often aligned with political parties that supported their goals. The Republican Party, in particular, was seen as more sympathetic to business and industry concerns. At the same time, the Democratic Party was more closely aligned with labour and other working-class interests.
Ligne 265 : Ligne 265 :


=== 1945-1994 ===
=== 1945-1994 ===
From 1945 to 1994, the United States experienced significant economic, social, and political changes. The country emerged from World War II as a global economic superpower, and the economy grew rapidly during this period. The factor endowments of the time period were still characterized by abundant land and scarce capital and labour. However, mobility had increased significantly as transportation and communication technologies continued to improve. During this time, class-based parties and associations continued to play a significant role in American political and social life. Labour unions and other organisations representing the interests of working people became more prominent and influential, and they often aligned with political parties that supported their goals. The Republican Party, in particular, was seen as more sympathetic to business and industry concerns. At the same time, the Democratic Party was more closely aligned with labour and other working-class interests.
From 1945 to 1994, the United States experienced significant economic, social, and political changes. The country emerged from World War II as a global economic superpower, and the economy grew rapidly during this period. The factor endowments of the time period were still characterized by abundant land and scarce capital and labour. However, mobility had increased significantly as transportation and communication technologies continued to improve. During this time, class-based parties and associations continued to play a significant role in American political and social life. Labour unions and other organisations representing the interests of working people became more prominent and influential, and they often aligned with political parties that supported their goals. The Republican Party, in particular, was seen as more sympathetic to business and industry concerns. At the same time, the Democratic Party was more closely aligned with labour and other working-class interests.


Industry groups also remained important during this period, as businesses sought to coordinate their efforts and advocate for their interests. These groups often had close ties to political parties and worked to influence policy decisions that would benefit their industries.
Industry groups also remained important during this period, as businesses sought to coordinate their efforts and advocate for their interests. These groups often had close ties to political parties and worked to influence policy decisions that would benefit their industries.
Ligne 294 : Ligne 294 :


=== Economic self-interest and role of knowledge ===
=== Economic self-interest and role of knowledge ===
Economic self-interest is a person’s desire to maximize their own economic well-being or gain. This can be a powerful motivator in shaping an individual’s views on trade and support for trade policies. For example, an individual who is employed in an industry that is heavily exposed to foreign competition may be more likely to support trade barriers if they believe it will help to protect their job or industry. On the other hand, an individual who stands to benefit from lower prices or increased access to foreign goods and services may be more likely to oppose trade barriers. The role of knowledge can also play a role in shaping an individual’s views on trade. For example, an individual who is more knowledgeable about the potential benefits and costs of trade may be more likely to take a nuanced view of trade policies rather than to support or oppose them based on economic self-interest alone. Likewise, an individual well-informed about the complex economic and social factors at play may be more likely to consider the trade-offs involved and weigh the potential costs and benefits of different policies.
Economic self-interest is a person's desire to maximize their own economic well-being or gain. This can be a powerful motivator in shaping an individual's views on trade and support for trade policies. For example, an individual who is employed in an industry that is heavily exposed to foreign competition may be more likely to support trade barriers if they believe it will help to protect their job or industry. On the other hand, an individual who stands to benefit from lower prices or increased access to foreign goods and services may be more likely to oppose trade barriers. The role of knowledge can also play a role in shaping an individual's views on trade. For example, an individual who is more knowledgeable about the potential benefits and costs of trade may be more likely to take a nuanced view of trade policies rather than to support or oppose them based on economic self-interest alone. Likewise, an individual well-informed about the complex economic and social factors at play may be more likely to consider the trade-offs involved and weigh the potential costs and benefits of different policies.


Increasing knowledge about trade and its potential impacts may lead individuals to align their preferences more closely with their economic self-interest. For example, an individual who is more knowledgeable about the potential benefits of trade may be more likely to support free trade policies if they benefit from lower prices or increased access to foreign goods and services. Similarly, an individual who is more knowledgeable about the potential costs of trade, such as job loss or wage stagnation in certain industries, may be more likely to support trade barriers if they feel that their economic interests would be threatened by foreign competition.
Increasing knowledge about trade and its potential impacts may lead individuals to align their preferences more closely with their economic self-interest. For example, an individual who is more knowledgeable about the potential benefits of trade may be more likely to support free trade policies if they benefit from lower prices or increased access to foreign goods and services. Similarly, an individual who is more knowledgeable about the potential costs of trade, such as job loss or wage stagnation in certain industries, may be more likely to support trade barriers if they feel that their economic interests would be threatened by foreign competition.


However, it is important to note that other factors, such as political ideology, values, and social norms, can also influence an individual’s views on trade and support for trade policies. An individual’s level of trade knowledge may not be the only determinant of their preferences, and other considerations may also influence their views. Additionally, the relationship between knowledge and preference may vary depending on the specific context and the details of the trade policies being considered.
However, it is important to note that other factors, such as political ideology, values, and social norms, can also influence an individual's views on trade and support for trade policies. An individual's level of trade knowledge may not be the only determinant of their preferences, and other considerations may also influence their views. Additionally, the relationship between knowledge and preference may vary depending on the specific context and the details of the trade policies being considered.


The Stolper-Samuelson theorem is a key result in the theory of international trade that describes the distributional consequences of trade. It states that trade liberalisation (i.e. the removal of trade barriers such as tariffs or quotas) will increase the price of the imported good, which will benefit domestic producers of that good. But, at the same time, the increased price will lead to a decrease in the demand for the domestic good, harming domestic producers of that good.
The Stolper-Samuelson theorem is a key result in the theory of international trade that describes the distributional consequences of trade. It states that trade liberalization (i.e. the removal of trade barriers such as tariffs or quotas) will increase the price of the imported good, which will benefit domestic producers of that good. But, at the same time, the increased price will lead to a decrease in the demand for the domestic good, harming domestic producers of that good.


Overall, the Stolper-Samuelson theorem suggests that trade liberalisation can have different impacts on different groups within a society, depending on the relative abundance of the factors of production (such as labour and capital) used in different industries. For example, in a country where labour is relatively abundant and capital is relatively scarce, trade liberalisation may lead to higher wages for workers in the importing sector and lower wages for workers in the exporting sector.
Overall, the Stolper-Samuelson theorem suggests that trade liberalization can have different impacts on different groups within a society, depending on the relative abundance of the factors of production (such as labour and capital) used in different industries. For example, in a country where labour is relatively abundant and capital is relatively scarce, trade liberalization may lead to higher wages for workers in the importing sector and lower wages for workers in the exporting sector.


Suppose individuals have trade beliefs that align with the Stolper-Samuelson theorem. In that case, they may view trade liberalisation differently depending on their position in the economy and the relative abundance of the factors of production they use. For example, an individual who is employed in a sector that uses relatively abundant factors of production (such as labour) may be more likely to support trade liberalisation. In contrast, an individual who is employed in a sector that uses relatively scarce factors of production (such as capital) may be more likely to oppose it.
Suppose individuals have trade beliefs that align with the Stolper-Samuelson theorem. In that case, they may view trade liberalization differently depending on their position in the economy and the relative abundance of the factors of production they use. For example, an individual who is employed in a sector that uses relatively abundant factors of production (such as labour) may be more likely to support trade liberalization. In contrast, an individual who is employed in a sector that uses relatively scarce factors of production (such as capital) may be more likely to oppose it.


=== Trade and presidential votes ===
=== Trade and presidential votes ===
Trade policy can be an important factor in presidential elections, as it can affect the economic well-being of different groups within a society. For example, trade liberalisation may lead to increased access to foreign goods and services, which can benefit consumers by lowering prices. At the same time, trade liberalisation may lead to job loss or wage stagnation in certain industries, harming workers and their families. As a result, trade policy can be a divisive issue in presidential elections, with different candidates offering different approaches to trade. For example, some candidates may support free trade and globalisation, while others may advocate for protectionist measures such as tariffs or trade barriers.
Trade policy can be an important factor in presidential elections, as it can affect the economic well-being of different groups within a society. For example, trade liberalization may lead to increased access to foreign goods and services, which can benefit consumers by lowering prices. At the same time, trade liberalization may lead to job loss or wage stagnation in certain industries, harming workers and their families. As a result, trade policy can be a divisive issue in presidential elections, with different candidates offering different approaches to trade. For example, some candidates may support free trade and globalization, while others may advocate for protectionist measures such as tariffs or trade barriers.


In general, the impact of trade policy on presidential votes will depend on the specific context and the details of the proposed trade policies. It may also depend on the relative importance of trade policy compared to other issues, such as healthcare, education, and taxation. Additionally, the preferences of different voter groups, such as workers, consumers, and business owners, may also influence the presidential vote.
In general, the impact of trade policy on presidential votes will depend on the specific context and the details of the proposed trade policies. It may also depend on the relative importance of trade policy compared to other issues, such as healthcare, education, and taxation. Additionally, the preferences of different voter groups, such as workers, consumers, and business owners, may also influence the presidential vote.
Ligne 313 : Ligne 313 :
Trade-related job insecurity may lead to reduced support for incumbents or candidates who are currently in office. Job insecurity refers to the uncertainty or risk that an individual may lose their job due to economic or other factors. If individuals feel that trade policies contribute to job insecurity in their industry, they may be more likely to support candidates who promise to address these concerns.
Trade-related job insecurity may lead to reduced support for incumbents or candidates who are currently in office. Job insecurity refers to the uncertainty or risk that an individual may lose their job due to economic or other factors. If individuals feel that trade policies contribute to job insecurity in their industry, they may be more likely to support candidates who promise to address these concerns.


However, it is important to note that other factors may also influence an individual’s support for incumbents. For example, an individual’s overall economic well-being, satisfaction with public services, and views on other issues such as healthcare and education may also shape their voting decisions. Additionally, the relationship between trade-related job insecurity and support for incumbents may vary depending on the specific context and the details of the trade policies being considered.
However, it is important to note that other factors may also influence an individual's support for incumbents. For example, an individual's overall economic well-being, satisfaction with public services, and views on other issues such as healthcare and education may also shape their voting decisions. Additionally, the relationship between trade-related job insecurity and support for incumbents may vary depending on the specific context and the details of the trade policies being considered.


Job insecurity is generally lower in industries that produce high-skilled services and goods and higher in industries that produce low-skilled manufacturing.
Job insecurity is generally lower in industries that produce high-skilled services and goods and higher in industries that produce low-skilled manufacturing.
Ligne 323 : Ligne 323 :
It is important to note that these generalizations may not hold true in all cases, and the level of job insecurity in a particular industry may depend on a range of factors, including the overall economic conditions, technological changes, and competition from foreign firms.
It is important to note that these generalizations may not hold true in all cases, and the level of job insecurity in a particular industry may depend on a range of factors, including the overall economic conditions, technological changes, and competition from foreign firms.


Individuals who feel they have lost out due to trade liberalisation or globalisation may demand compensation, align with left-leaning political parties, or vote against incumbents.
Individuals who feel they have lost out due to trade liberalization or globalization may demand compensation, align with left-leaning political parties, or vote against incumbents.


Trade liberalisation and globalisation can have different impacts on different groups within a society, depending on the relative abundance of the factors of production (such as labour and capital) used in different industries. For example, in a country where labour is relatively abundant and capital is relatively scarce, trade liberalisation may lead to higher wages for workers in the importing sector and lower wages for workers in the exporting sector. Workers in the exporting sector who feel that they have lost out due to trade liberalisation may demand compensation and align with left-leaning parties or vote against incumbents to protect their economic interests.
Trade liberalization and globalization can have different impacts on different groups within a society, depending on the relative abundance of the factors of production (such as labour and capital) used in different industries. For example, in a country where labour is relatively abundant and capital is relatively scarce, trade liberalization may lead to higher wages for workers in the importing sector and lower wages for workers in the exporting sector. Workers in the exporting sector who feel that they have lost out due to trade liberalization may demand compensation and align with left-leaning parties or vote against incumbents to protect their economic interests.


It is important to note that this relationship may not hold true in all cases. A range of other factors, such as overall economic conditions, individual characteristics, and views on other issues, may influence the demand for compensation and political realignment. Additionally, the relationship may vary over time and across different geographical regions.
It is important to note that this relationship may not hold true in all cases. A range of other factors, such as overall economic conditions, individual characteristics, and views on other issues, may influence the demand for compensation and political realignment. Additionally, the relationship may vary over time and across different geographical regions.


Trade opening, such as the influx of Chinese imports following the ‘China shock’ (a term used to describe the rapid increase in Chinese imports to the US in the late 1990s and early 2000s), may lead to a rise in political polarisation and the emergence of political candidates with extreme views on both sides of the political spectrum.
== Other electoral effects ==
 
Trade liberalisation and globalisation can have different impacts on different groups within a society, depending on the relative abundance of the factors of production (such as labour and capital) used in various industries. For example, in a country where labour is relatively abundant and capital is relatively scarce, trade liberalisation may lead to higher wages for workers in the importing sector and lower wages for workers in the exporting sector. This can create economic disparities and lead to social tensions, which political candidates with extreme views on either side of the political spectrum may exploit.
 
It is important to note that this relationship may not hold true in all cases, and a range of other factors, such as overall economic conditions, individual characteristics, and views on other issues, may influence the rise of political candidates with extreme views. Additionally, the relationship may vary over time and across different geographical regions.


= Conclusion =
= Conclusion =
== Implications ==
Countries are not inherently mercantilist. Mercantilism is an economic theory that advocates for a country to increase its wealth and power by maximising exports and minimising imports through trade barriers and other protectionist measures. While some countries may adopt mercantilist policies in order to promote their economic interests, other countries may take a more liberal approach to trade and support free trade and globalisation. The choice of trade policy can depend on various factors, including a country’s economic circumstances, political ideology, and strategic interests. Additionally, it is important to note that trade policy is just one aspect of a country’s economic and foreign policy and is not the only determinant of a country’s wealth and power. Other factors, such as a country’s natural resources, technological capabilities, and human capital, can also play a role in shaping its economic success.
Trade can significantly affect domestic politics, as it can affect the economic well-being of different groups within a society. Trade policy can be a divisive issue, with different social groups having different views on the benefits and costs of trade liberalisation and protectionism.
For example, trade liberalisation may lead to increased access to foreign goods and services, which can benefit consumers by lowering prices. But, at the same time, trade liberalisation may lead to job loss or wage stagnation in certain industries, harming workers and their families. This can create economic disparities and lead to social tensions, which political candidates with extreme views on either side of the political spectrum may exploit.
Trade policy can also impact a country’s foreign relations and its ability to influence events on the global stage. For example, a country’s trade policies may affect its ability to negotiate trade agreements or participate in international organisations. As a result, trade policy can be important in shaping a country’s domestic politics and position in the global economy.
Trade policy can significantly impact the economic well-being of different groups within a society, and the distributional effects of trade can depend on a range of factors, including factor endowment and factor mobility. Factor endowment refers to a country’s relative abundance of the factors of production, such as labour and capital, that are used to produce goods and services. In contrast, factor mobility refers to the ease with which these factors can move between industries or countries. The distributional effects of trade may depend on the relative abundance of different factors of production in a country and the degree of factor mobility, as well as other economic and social factors. Therefore, it is important to consider these factors when evaluating the potential impacts of trade policy on different groups within a society.
== Institutions ==
In a democracy, economic performance is often considered an essential factor in determining the success or popularity of a government. This is because economic performance can affect the well-being of citizens and the overall prosperity of a society.
Trade agreements can be seen as signals of a government’s commitment to promoting the general welfare of its citizens, as they can affect the access of consumers to foreign goods and services and the competitiveness of domestic industries. For example, trade agreements that liberalise trade and promote free trade can benefit consumers by increasing access to lower-priced goods and services and increasing competition, leading to lower prices and better-quality products. However, at the same time, trade agreements can also negatively impact certain industries and workers, as they may be exposed to increased competition from foreign firms.
Overall, the effects of trade agreements on economic performance can be complex and depend on a range of factors, including the agreement’s specific terms, the country’s economic circumstances, and the different stakeholders’ views. Therefore, governments must carefully consider these factors when negotiating and implementing trade agreements to promote the general welfare of their citizens.
The electoral system can influence how political organisation occurs within a society, including the extent to which it is based on sectoral or class lines.
In majoritarian electoral systems, such as first-past-the-post systems, political parties tend to focus on winning a majority of votes in a particular geographic area, such as a district or a state. As a result, political organisations may be more likely to occur along sectoral or industry lines, as parties may seek to appeal to voters with similar economic interests.
In proportional electoral systems, such as party-list systems, parties are awarded seats in proportion to the number of votes they receive. This can encourage the formation of broader, ideologically-based parties that represent a range of economic interests. As a result, political organisation may be more likely to occur along class lines, with parties representing the interests of different economic groups within society.
Overall, the electoral system can shape how political parties and organisations form and prioritise issues. Therefore, it is crucial to consider the specific characteristics of the electoral system when evaluating the potential impacts of trade policy on different groups within a society.
Veto players are political actors with the power to block or veto policy changes. In a political system with fewer veto players, it may be easier for policymakers to change tariffs or other trade policies, as fewer actors can block these changes.
For example, suppose a country has a centralised decision-making process with a single executive branch or a small group of key decision-makers. In that case, it may be easier for policymakers to change tariffs or other trade policies without facing significant opposition. On the other hand, if a country has a more decentralised decision-making process, with multiple veto players who can block policy changes, it may be more difficult for policymakers to change tariffs or other trade policies.
It is important to note that the number of veto players is just one factor that can affect the ease of policy change and other factors, such as the strength of interest groups, the extent of public support for the policy change, and the overall political environment, can also play a role. It is, therefore, essential to consider the specific characteristics of a country’s political system when evaluating the potential impacts of trade policy on different groups within a society.
Notez bien que toutes les contributions à Baripedia sont considérées comme publiées sous les termes de la Attribution-ShareAlike 4.0 International (CC BY-SA 4.0) (voir My wiki:Copyrights pour plus de détails). Si vous ne désirez pas que vos écrits soient modifiés et distribués à volonté, merci de ne pas les soumettre ici.
Vous nous promettez aussi que vous avez écrit ceci vous-même, ou que vous l’avez copié d’une source placée dans le domaine public ou d’une ressource libre similaire. N’utilisez aucun travail sous droits d’auteur sans autorisation expresse !

Pour créer, modifier ou publier cette page, veuillez répondre à la question ci-dessous (plus d’informations) :

Annuler Aide pour la modification (s’ouvre dans une nouvelle fenêtre)