Trade policy instruments

De Baripedia


Languages

Introduction[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

We are moving from a positive analysis in which the determinants of trade flows are explained to a normative analysis in which the impact of trade policy on welfare is studied, as well as the distributional effects between consumers and producers.

We move from a general equilibrium analysis to a partial equilibrium analysis

Before studying the impact of trade policy on welfare, we recall some analytical tools:

  • The import demand curve
  • The export supply curve
  • The consumer surplus
  • The producer surplus

The domestic import demand curve[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

When the price of the good increases, the demand expressed by domestic consumers decreases, while the quantities offered by producers increase. This leads to a decrease in import demand.

Économie internationale courbe de demande d’importation domestique 1.png

The foreign export supply curve[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

When the price of the good rises, foreign production increases, while foreign demand falls. This leads to an increase in the quantities of products available for export.

Économie internationale courbe d’offre d’exportation étrangère 1.png

Consumer surplus[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

Économie internationale surplus du consommateur 1.png

The producer's surplus[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

Économie internationale surplus du producteur 1.png

Tariffs (customs duty)[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

Analysis of the impact on trade flows of the introduction of a tariff by a large country (which may influence international prices)[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

Économie internationale droit de douane graphe 1.png

The introduction of a customs duty increases the price on the domestic market, decreases the price on the foreign market and reduces the volume of international trade.

Welfare impact analysis following the introduction of a t-tariff by a large country (which may influence international prices)[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

For the small country that cannot influence international prices, it is sufficient to keep world prices at following the introduction of the tariff (i.e. the surface area ( disappears). The fare can never increase well-being - no optimal fare)

Économie internationale droit de douane graphe 2.png

Net effect =

= gain in terms of trade

loss of efficiency due to distortion of production loss of efficiency due to distortion of consumption

There is a welfare gain if (due to improved terms of trade). There is an optimal tariff.

Considerations[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

The impact of a tariff can always be reproduced by introducing a consumption tax and a subsidy to producers identical to the tariff.

This implies that if the objective of the tariff is to:

  • protect producers or subsidise their production (e.g. agriculture in Europe), a production subsidy is much more efficient than a tariff, because it does not distort consumption (so the trade protection side of the CAP is difficult to justify).
  • Collecting revenue for the government (e.g. Sub-Saharan African countries), a consumption tax is more efficient because it does not distort the production side.
  • restricting the consumption of a good (e.g., beer in Egypt), a prohibitive consumption tax is much more efficient than a tariff because it does not distort the production side of the equation

So, all these finance ministers have never taken an international trade course? They certainly have, and the explanation is often on the political process side in determining the instruments to be used in each case.

For the CAP, a subsidy is always politically more expensive than a tariff (which actually generates revenue for the government).

In Sub-Saharan Africa, it is very difficult to collect revenue domestically (administration capacity is very low), and the cost of collecting revenue is much lower in customs (smuggling becomes a problem!).

This could also explain the case of Egypt, but production should then be banned. Producer interests are probably an important part of the explanation.

Export subsidies[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

Analysis of the welfare impact following the introduction of an export subsidy by a large country (which may influence international prices)[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

For the small country that cannot influence international prices it is sufficient to keep world prices at following the introduction of the subsidy (i.e. , and disappear).

Économie internationale subventions à l’exportation graphe 1.png

Subsidy = public aid to companies that sell part of their production abroad.

There is always a welfare loss (no optimal export subsidy).

Application: the European Union's Common Agricultural Policy[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

Économie internationale subventions à l’exportation politique agricole commune de l’Union européenne graphe 1.png

Initial objective = to guarantee high prices for European farmers

At the outset EU importing agricultural products therefore Import tax allows the objective to be achieved

But in the 70's : EU Production > EU Conso

European authorities buy,

At the end of 1985, stock so huge that an export subsidy (in addition to taxes) was introduced,

Reduction of the world price, Increases the necessary amount of subsidy,

The new rules are expensive for European consumers and taxpayers (in 2007, advertising subsidy = 36% of the value of the agricultural production) + for non-European countries exporting these products, Reforms with "decoupling" of agricultural subsidies

Import quotas[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

Effect of a quota in a small country (which does not influence world prices)[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

Quota = legal limit of imported quantities

Économie internationale effet d'un quota dans un petit pays 1.png

reduces imports if quota effectively binding

If binding: systematically increase the domestic price in the sector protected by the quota

Example of the impact of a quota on trade: China and the Multifibre Arrangement[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

Changes in Clothing and Textiles Exports to the United States after the MFA, 2004–2005.

Source: Feenstra and Taylor 2012 p. 271, based on Harrigan and Barrows, 2009.


After the expiration of the Multifibre Arrangement (MFA), the value of clothing and textiles exports from China rose dramatically, as shown in panel (a). This reflects the surge in the quantity of exports that were formerly constrained under the MFA as well as a shift to Chinese exports from other, higher- cost producers such as Hong Kong, Taiwan, and South Korea.

Source: Feenstra and Taylor 2012 p. 271, based on Harrigan and Barrows, 2009.

In panel (b), we see that the prices of goods constrained by the MFA typically fell by more than the average change in export prices after the MFA’s expiry. This is exactly what our theory of quotas predicts: the removal of quotas lowers import prices for consumers.

Other considerations[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

Equivalence of quotas and tariffs in a small country (which does not influence world prices)

Let's take the example of the sugar quota in the US: An import quota of (9.3-7.9)=1.4 million tonnes has the same impact as a specific tariff of (417.40-157.60)=$259.8 per tonne.

But the equivalency holds if the rents associated with the quota are captured by the government. This will happen if, for example, the government sells the import rights at auction.

But it is common to give them to domestic importers. So there is no change in aggregate welfare, but different distributional effects.

They are sometimes given to exporters abroad (e.g. VERs). In this case the rents are captured by foreigners and the cost of the quota to the domestic economy becomes much greater than the cost of the equivalent tariff.

More importantly, a quota and a tariff will not be equivalent if there is imperfect competition.

Take the example of a domestic monopoly: trade forces it to behave competitively (the pro-competitive effect of trade or "import discipline hypothesis"). A tariff will have a similar effect, because it sets the price at which it must sell at the world price plus the tariff (its marginal income is a horizontal line). But in the case of the quota, the quantities imported are fixed and there is no threat that they will increase if the monopolist increases the price. So he can continue to abuse his monopoly power over residual demand (once the import quota is deducted). So the price paid by consumers will be much higher than in the case of the "equivalent" tariff.

The non-equivalence of the quota and the "equivalent" tariff in imperfect competition (the case of the monopoly)

Économie internationale non équivalence du quota et le tarif équivalent en concurrence imparfaite 1.png

Other trade policy instruments[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

Voluntary Export Restrictions[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

The VER (RVE in French: Restrictions Volontaires aux Exportations). They appear to avoid the prohibition of the GATT Tokyo Round of negotiations (1979) which prohibits the use of quantitative barriers by importing countries. The result is a transfer of rents abroad, plus an improvement in the quality of the exporting country's products.

Prices of American Small Cars Under the VER on Japanese car imports : The average price of U.S. cars rose very rapidly when the quota was first imposed: from $4,200 in 1979 to $6,000 in 1981, or a 43% increase over two years. Only a very small part of that increase was explained by quality improvements, and in the later years of the quota, U.S. quality did not rise by as much as it did in the Japanese imports.

Économie internationale restrictions volontaires aux exportations graphe exemple 1.png

Prices of Japanese Car Imports Under the “voluntary” export restraint (VER) on Japanese car imports, the average price rose from $5,150 to $8,050 between 1980 and 1985. Of that $2,900 increase, $1,100 was the result of quota rent increases earned by Japanese producers. Another $1,650 was the result of quality improvements in the Japanese cars, which became heavier and wider, with improved horsepower, transmissions, and so on. The remaining $150 is the amount that import prices would have risen under free trade.

Économie internationale restrictions volontaires aux exportations graphe exemple 2.png

The VER (RVE in French: Restrictions Volontaires aux Exportations). They appear to avoid the prohibition of the GATT Tokyo Round of negotiations (1979) which prohibits the use of quantitative barriers by importing countries. The result is a transfer of rents abroad, plus an improvement in the quality of the exporting country's products.

Subsidized export credits

Public procurement (discrimination between domestic and foreign companies)

Administrative barriers

  • Technical regulations (e.g. requirements in labels, electrical sockets, etc...)
  • Sanitary, phytosanitary barriers (aflatoxin in peanuts)
  • Customs procedures
  • behind the border: e.g. longer delays in the registration of foreign trademarks

Local content rules

Anti-dumping tariff

Which are more restrictive today? Tariffs or non-tariff measures?[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

OECD average protection in agriculture and manufacturing

Économie internationale protection moyenne de l’ OCDE en agriculture et manufacture 1.png

Private Optimum versus Social Optimum[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

Positive production externalities (e.g. R&D)[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

Économie internationale externalités positives de production 1.png

The tariff makes it possible to reach the social optimum of production at point B, but it introduces a consumer loss. A production subsidy would have made it possible to wait for B, and the gain in positive externality for the other producers without introducing the consumer loss. The subsidy is the optimal policy, and the tariff is only a "second best" (second best policy).

But subsidies are politically and administratively costly

Annexes[modifier | modifier le wikicode]

References[modifier | modifier le wikicode]